Article and video can be found at this link
Graphic below is from the Houston Chronicle:
TxDOT: Houston is home to Texas' most-congested roadway
05:30 PM CDT on Wednesday, September 2, 2009
Associated Press and Brad Woodard / 11 News
AUSTIN, Texas -- A state agency has proof of what many Texas drivers already know. Harris County, with its nearly 4 million residents, has a lot of traffic. The Department of Transportation says a stretch of Interstate 45 in the Houston area tops the list of the state’s 100 most congested roadways.
The roadway from South Loop 8 to Interstate 610 totaled nearly 450,000 hours of delay a mile and almost 4.3 million hours of delay annually at a cost of $88 million. “You’ve got to keep in mind 1-45 was built 20 plus years ago,” said P.E. transportation engineer Gonzalo Camacho. “It’s probably about time it needs to be reconstructed.”
In fact, Harris County is home to six of the state’s top ten most congested roads, but something sets I-45 apart. You see, I-45 is a hurricane evacuation route and remember what happened during Hurricane Rita. “In my mind it sets it as a priority versus other highways at the state level. Look at Houston, the fourth largest city in the U.S. It needs to be a priority,” said Camacho.
Three stretches in Harris County and two in Dallas County, including No. 2 from I-635 to Woodall Rodgers Freeway, make up the top five most congested segments.
All roads in Texas were part of the analysis, but for practical purposes only freeways, tollways, expressways, frontage roads and certain artery streets were included.
References:
List: TxDOT's 100 Most Congested Roadways
Thursday, September 03, 2009
Friday, May 15, 2009
May 8, 1988 Article: Seattle - Tunnel Vission Vladimir Khazak Plans His Moves Years in Advance
A superb article about a Russian immigrant who happens to be a civil engineer and happens to know tunnels. Note the year when the article was published.
TUNNEL VISION VLADIMIR KHAZAK PLANS HIS MOVES YEARS IN ADVANCE
By James Wallace P-I Reporter
SUNDAY, May 8, 1988
Vladimir Khazak looks out his window at the cars and Metro buses clogging Second Avenue. It is the evening rush hour, and a massive traffic jam stretches north for many city blocks. On the street below, the sounds of horns, brakes, tires and engines ricochet between the walls of office buildings as people leave their jobs and head home - the sound of a city on the move.
Skyscrapers are rising. The waterfront is getting a face lift. A new city park is taking shape. And under Third Avenue, a block from the Exchange Building, crews are working 60 feet under ground on Metro's twin bus tunnels. Two years from now, those tunnels are supposed to carry riders on a 1.3- mile underground odyssey through the heart of downtown Seattle, avoiding the mess of cars and buses that now inch their way along Second Avenue below.
The sounds of that traffic jam are faint by the time they reach the window of Khazak's 13th-floor office. Khazak is construction manager of the half-billion-dollar bus tunnel project. It is a job that requires all the strategy of a chess master, someone able to analyze several moves ahead, anticipating and overcoming any challenge. "I am a chess player," Khazak says. "I like to strategize. I think in steps . . .. "But if you play only a few moves in advance you don't have a chance. You need to think a dozen or more."
And who plays chess like that better than a Russian?
Twelves years ago, Vladimir Khazak was an engineer from Leningrad, supervising construction of waste-water treatment plants in the Soviet Union. Today, he is in charge of one of Seattle's biggest, most costly and most ambitious public works projects.
He turns from the window toward a huge flow chart covering much of one office wall. Hundreds of boxes indicate critical construction deadlines. Lines connect to the boxes. Other lines connect to those lines and still more to those lines. It's an intricate puzzle, a step-by-step guide to hundreds of construction tasks that must be completed on time if the bus tunnels are to open on schedule. The chart ends in mid-1990.
"The most important thing," he says, "is to see the future all the time . . .things that have to be done today must not be allowed to block the picture of what needs to be done for tomorrow."
Khazak is the perfect construction manager for such an important project, say those who know him best. "He came to this project with the reputation as a tough project manager with a single-mindedness about getting the job completed and on time," says David Kalberer, superintendent of the tunnel project. "But he has much superior people skills than was the reputation that preceded him...'
Kalberer and Khazak have offices at opposite ends of the 13th floor of the Exchange Building. Kalberer formerly managed Metro's intergovernmental relations. He never before managed a large construction project. He is given to flashy European- style clothes. Khazak has been involved in construction management much of his adult life. He dresses conservatively. They met on the job.
Khazak is known around Metro for his dry humor and quick wit. And for his famous, oft-quoted "Russian proverbs." Ruth Williamson, Khazak's secretary, says her favorite is one about a tug boat captain. As she tells it:
The captain operated his tug in a harbor with a dangerous entrance. Many ships were wrecked on the rocks. But the captain always got his ships safely through. Each time he hooked up to a ship, he would pull a piece of paper from his pocket, read the paper and then navigate safely. One day, before he was about to hook up to a ship, the captain pulled out his piece of paper and fell over dead from a heart attack. Everyone rushed up to read the paper and learn his secret. The paper said: "The bow is in the front and the stern is in the back."
"That's just how Vladimir looks at things . . . very simply," says Williamson. "But a lot of people don't remember it." She describes Khazak as a tough boss to work for, demanding with a strong personality. But there is genuine affection for the man who went through several secretaries before her.
Kalberer, struggling to find the flavor of the man, says Khazak sees people and life as a story. "If you don't have a story to tell, you are not in sync," he says.
Khazak's story begins in the U.S.S.R. His parents were from Leningrad. As befitting a future engineer, his parents helped to build the city he was born in. In the early 1930s, during the Russian equivalent of the Alaska gold rush, his parents crossed the Ural Mountains by train, traveling the length of the country to help build the city of Magadan on the southeast coast.
His father was a civil engineer. His mother worked as an economist. Khazak was born there, in Magadan, in 1944. The family did not return to Leningrad until 1948, three years after the war. Khazak grew up in Leningrad and in 1961 went to the university there to study civil engineering. After graduating, he held a succession of jobs building waste-water treatment plants for pulp and paper mills.
Thanks to a trade agreement - partly due to the late U.S. Sen. Henry Jackson - that allowed Soviet Jews to immigrate to Israel, Khazak was able to leave the Soviet Union in July 1976, with his wife Lyudmila and their son Misha. They now also have an 8-year-old daughter, Michele. His parents left the following year, with his sister and brother-in-law. The family lives in a home they built in Bellevue. His mother died three years ago.
Khazak's family is Jewish. His wife's family is Russian and lives in Leningrad. He struggles for the right words when asked why he left.
"It's very complex question," he says. "Some people will say for political reasons . . . no, its not pure political . . . it's political, economical . . . it's sense of adventure . . . all the above. You grow in the system and you come to the point of certain disillusionment and you are looking for bigger and better things to do with your life . . . suddenly such possibilities open. I just hate to miss opportunity."
The Khazaks left with seven suitcases and the equivalent of about $200 American money. First stop was Vienna, Austria. Khazak will never forget those first impressions of life in the West.
"You go outside to see how Vienna looks and what kinds of cars are on the street," he remembers. "The picture of capitalism is changing in your head in a matter of seconds . . . not in a matter of hours. It's very interesting . . . that what you learned for 15 years in school about Marxism and Leninism could be destroyed in five minutes when you walk in a Vienna supermarket . . .."
Instead of going on to Israel, they decided to go to the United States. A Jewish immigration organization helped work out the details. "They asked me where I wanted to go. I said I want to go where pulp and paper industry is," Khazak says. "They sent us to Seattle."
They were met at the airport by a Seattle family in a volunteer organization helping resettle Jewish immigrants. The family helped the Khazaks find an apartment on Capitol Hill and provided other support until Khazak eventually found work.
That first trip from Sea-Tac to Seattle was unforgettable, Khazak says. He had never seen so many big cars. And he had no idea the United States could be so green. "I was kind of under impression that United States was a smokestack from the Pacific to the Atlantic . . . a lot of concrete," he says.
Most Russians have two impressions of the United States, he adds. Both are wrong. Some see this country as the "toughest place on planet," he says. "A terrible place. A country of unemployed, exploited, abused racially, sexually . . . it's Ku Klux Klan and organized crime . . . a lot of people believe this. Others believe the United States is "the paradise of the earth. Buildings are big, people are big, cars are big, salaries are big and everything is very cheap . . ." His own preconceived view was that America was a country "with a lot of possibilities and opportunities."
Khazak pauses with his thoughts, his eyes glancing at a Russian calendar on the wall of his office that was sent to him by an old friend in Leningrad. The calendar shows a beautiful Leningrad park.
"I did not see it right," he says. "I could never imagine the type of housing here . . . houses with backyards and all these rhododendrons. I thought that if in Soviet Union we have apartment buildings, then in United States apartment buildings should be bigger and taller and wider . . . it means you are trying to create something without the proper information."
Khazak has several funny stories about those early days in Seattle. He recalls walking with his wife into the Safeway store at Mercer and Broadway for the first time. "We could not sleep for a week," he says. "One question in your head is . . . how in the hell is it possible to produce it all?"
He was also confused by one of the first television programs he watched: "Streets of San Francisco," a police action show staring Michael Douglas and Karl Malden. "I could not figure out why the hell they were showing this," he says. "We all were raised in what they call social realism, that objective of art is to educate and develop positive feelings in people, right? What was (the) objective of 'Streets of San Francisco?' "
And he will never forget one of his first job interviews with a local engineering company. The president of the company who interviewed him was from China, and spoke with a heavy accent. He left that interview, he says, without having understood one word. He was also stumped during another job interview, when he was asked how much money he wanted to make. Those are not questions employers ask in the Soviet Union.
"It was an impossible question for me," he says. "I finally said I wanted to make about $500 a week. I was called a few days later and told I could start work for $800." Instead, he took a job in Aberdeen, working on a waste-water collection and treatment project. He later worked in Olympia for two years on waste-water treatment projects there.
In 1982, Khazak went to work for Metro, as construction manager of a $120 million Renton treatment plant project. Three years later, he was construction manager of the tunnel project, already in its final design phase.
He was taking command of a project as controversial as it was costly. The proposal to build the tunnel was never put to a vote of the people. The downtown business district would be disrupted for several years. Critics characterized the tunnel as a colossal mistake that would do little to ease downtown traffic congestion. But Khazak was not intimidated. He welcomed the challenge. This is a man who says he would have liked to have been construction manager for the ill-fated WPPSS project.
"The problem with WPPSS was that they forgot what was their purpose, to produce cheap energy," he says.
Had Khazak been involved in the tunnel design, he would have argued for a broader vision of the city's future. "If it would be up to me to plan it, I would try and convince people that it be (a) bigger project than it is now," he says, "bigger in the sense it should be more flexible for the future use . . . "
Pam Hoppes, Metro's right-of-way supervisor who has been involved in complex negotiations with property owners whose business were altered, destroyed or affected by the bus tunnel, recalls an early meeting with Khazak. "He looked at me," and asked, 'Why are we building only one tunnel?' " she says. " 'Why don't we drill two on top of each and move the Alaskan Way Viaduct under the bus tunnel?'
"And I thought, 'I love this guy.' "
Every other weekend, Khazak takes his 8-year-old daughter on a tour of the tunnel project. It has consumed much of his life the past two years. "It's much more than a job, " he says. "It's very big part of your life. I spend with this job more time than I spend with my family."
Khazak has become attached to this area. There are friends here. There are roots. Perhaps not as deep as those he dug up when he left the Soviet Union, but it would not be easy to leave.
"As a good project manager, I will tell you that everything is negotiable," he says when asked if he would leave Seattle for another job when the tunnel project is finished. He looks out the window at the city below.
"I'm doing this because I like to do it, because I know how to do it, and because I'm paid to do it," he says after a while. "And if I do it really well, and people think that I do it really well, then I want them to allow me to do bigger and better things."
wj
TUNNEL VISION VLADIMIR KHAZAK PLANS HIS MOVES YEARS IN ADVANCE
By James Wallace P-I Reporter
SUNDAY, May 8, 1988
Vladimir Khazak looks out his window at the cars and Metro buses clogging Second Avenue. It is the evening rush hour, and a massive traffic jam stretches north for many city blocks. On the street below, the sounds of horns, brakes, tires and engines ricochet between the walls of office buildings as people leave their jobs and head home - the sound of a city on the move.
Skyscrapers are rising. The waterfront is getting a face lift. A new city park is taking shape. And under Third Avenue, a block from the Exchange Building, crews are working 60 feet under ground on Metro's twin bus tunnels. Two years from now, those tunnels are supposed to carry riders on a 1.3- mile underground odyssey through the heart of downtown Seattle, avoiding the mess of cars and buses that now inch their way along Second Avenue below.
The sounds of that traffic jam are faint by the time they reach the window of Khazak's 13th-floor office. Khazak is construction manager of the half-billion-dollar bus tunnel project. It is a job that requires all the strategy of a chess master, someone able to analyze several moves ahead, anticipating and overcoming any challenge. "I am a chess player," Khazak says. "I like to strategize. I think in steps . . .. "But if you play only a few moves in advance you don't have a chance. You need to think a dozen or more."
And who plays chess like that better than a Russian?
Twelves years ago, Vladimir Khazak was an engineer from Leningrad, supervising construction of waste-water treatment plants in the Soviet Union. Today, he is in charge of one of Seattle's biggest, most costly and most ambitious public works projects.
He turns from the window toward a huge flow chart covering much of one office wall. Hundreds of boxes indicate critical construction deadlines. Lines connect to the boxes. Other lines connect to those lines and still more to those lines. It's an intricate puzzle, a step-by-step guide to hundreds of construction tasks that must be completed on time if the bus tunnels are to open on schedule. The chart ends in mid-1990.
"The most important thing," he says, "is to see the future all the time . . .things that have to be done today must not be allowed to block the picture of what needs to be done for tomorrow."
Khazak is the perfect construction manager for such an important project, say those who know him best. "He came to this project with the reputation as a tough project manager with a single-mindedness about getting the job completed and on time," says David Kalberer, superintendent of the tunnel project. "But he has much superior people skills than was the reputation that preceded him...'
Kalberer and Khazak have offices at opposite ends of the 13th floor of the Exchange Building. Kalberer formerly managed Metro's intergovernmental relations. He never before managed a large construction project. He is given to flashy European- style clothes. Khazak has been involved in construction management much of his adult life. He dresses conservatively. They met on the job.
Khazak is known around Metro for his dry humor and quick wit. And for his famous, oft-quoted "Russian proverbs." Ruth Williamson, Khazak's secretary, says her favorite is one about a tug boat captain. As she tells it:
The captain operated his tug in a harbor with a dangerous entrance. Many ships were wrecked on the rocks. But the captain always got his ships safely through. Each time he hooked up to a ship, he would pull a piece of paper from his pocket, read the paper and then navigate safely. One day, before he was about to hook up to a ship, the captain pulled out his piece of paper and fell over dead from a heart attack. Everyone rushed up to read the paper and learn his secret. The paper said: "The bow is in the front and the stern is in the back."
"That's just how Vladimir looks at things . . . very simply," says Williamson. "But a lot of people don't remember it." She describes Khazak as a tough boss to work for, demanding with a strong personality. But there is genuine affection for the man who went through several secretaries before her.
Kalberer, struggling to find the flavor of the man, says Khazak sees people and life as a story. "If you don't have a story to tell, you are not in sync," he says.
Khazak's story begins in the U.S.S.R. His parents were from Leningrad. As befitting a future engineer, his parents helped to build the city he was born in. In the early 1930s, during the Russian equivalent of the Alaska gold rush, his parents crossed the Ural Mountains by train, traveling the length of the country to help build the city of Magadan on the southeast coast.
His father was a civil engineer. His mother worked as an economist. Khazak was born there, in Magadan, in 1944. The family did not return to Leningrad until 1948, three years after the war. Khazak grew up in Leningrad and in 1961 went to the university there to study civil engineering. After graduating, he held a succession of jobs building waste-water treatment plants for pulp and paper mills.
Thanks to a trade agreement - partly due to the late U.S. Sen. Henry Jackson - that allowed Soviet Jews to immigrate to Israel, Khazak was able to leave the Soviet Union in July 1976, with his wife Lyudmila and their son Misha. They now also have an 8-year-old daughter, Michele. His parents left the following year, with his sister and brother-in-law. The family lives in a home they built in Bellevue. His mother died three years ago.
Khazak's family is Jewish. His wife's family is Russian and lives in Leningrad. He struggles for the right words when asked why he left.
"It's very complex question," he says. "Some people will say for political reasons . . . no, its not pure political . . . it's political, economical . . . it's sense of adventure . . . all the above. You grow in the system and you come to the point of certain disillusionment and you are looking for bigger and better things to do with your life . . . suddenly such possibilities open. I just hate to miss opportunity."
The Khazaks left with seven suitcases and the equivalent of about $200 American money. First stop was Vienna, Austria. Khazak will never forget those first impressions of life in the West.
"You go outside to see how Vienna looks and what kinds of cars are on the street," he remembers. "The picture of capitalism is changing in your head in a matter of seconds . . . not in a matter of hours. It's very interesting . . . that what you learned for 15 years in school about Marxism and Leninism could be destroyed in five minutes when you walk in a Vienna supermarket . . .."
Instead of going on to Israel, they decided to go to the United States. A Jewish immigration organization helped work out the details. "They asked me where I wanted to go. I said I want to go where pulp and paper industry is," Khazak says. "They sent us to Seattle."
They were met at the airport by a Seattle family in a volunteer organization helping resettle Jewish immigrants. The family helped the Khazaks find an apartment on Capitol Hill and provided other support until Khazak eventually found work.
That first trip from Sea-Tac to Seattle was unforgettable, Khazak says. He had never seen so many big cars. And he had no idea the United States could be so green. "I was kind of under impression that United States was a smokestack from the Pacific to the Atlantic . . . a lot of concrete," he says.
Most Russians have two impressions of the United States, he adds. Both are wrong. Some see this country as the "toughest place on planet," he says. "A terrible place. A country of unemployed, exploited, abused racially, sexually . . . it's Ku Klux Klan and organized crime . . . a lot of people believe this. Others believe the United States is "the paradise of the earth. Buildings are big, people are big, cars are big, salaries are big and everything is very cheap . . ." His own preconceived view was that America was a country "with a lot of possibilities and opportunities."
Khazak pauses with his thoughts, his eyes glancing at a Russian calendar on the wall of his office that was sent to him by an old friend in Leningrad. The calendar shows a beautiful Leningrad park.
"I did not see it right," he says. "I could never imagine the type of housing here . . . houses with backyards and all these rhododendrons. I thought that if in Soviet Union we have apartment buildings, then in United States apartment buildings should be bigger and taller and wider . . . it means you are trying to create something without the proper information."
Khazak has several funny stories about those early days in Seattle. He recalls walking with his wife into the Safeway store at Mercer and Broadway for the first time. "We could not sleep for a week," he says. "One question in your head is . . . how in the hell is it possible to produce it all?"
He was also confused by one of the first television programs he watched: "Streets of San Francisco," a police action show staring Michael Douglas and Karl Malden. "I could not figure out why the hell they were showing this," he says. "We all were raised in what they call social realism, that objective of art is to educate and develop positive feelings in people, right? What was (the) objective of 'Streets of San Francisco?' "
And he will never forget one of his first job interviews with a local engineering company. The president of the company who interviewed him was from China, and spoke with a heavy accent. He left that interview, he says, without having understood one word. He was also stumped during another job interview, when he was asked how much money he wanted to make. Those are not questions employers ask in the Soviet Union.
"It was an impossible question for me," he says. "I finally said I wanted to make about $500 a week. I was called a few days later and told I could start work for $800." Instead, he took a job in Aberdeen, working on a waste-water collection and treatment project. He later worked in Olympia for two years on waste-water treatment projects there.
In 1982, Khazak went to work for Metro, as construction manager of a $120 million Renton treatment plant project. Three years later, he was construction manager of the tunnel project, already in its final design phase.
He was taking command of a project as controversial as it was costly. The proposal to build the tunnel was never put to a vote of the people. The downtown business district would be disrupted for several years. Critics characterized the tunnel as a colossal mistake that would do little to ease downtown traffic congestion. But Khazak was not intimidated. He welcomed the challenge. This is a man who says he would have liked to have been construction manager for the ill-fated WPPSS project.
"The problem with WPPSS was that they forgot what was their purpose, to produce cheap energy," he says.
Had Khazak been involved in the tunnel design, he would have argued for a broader vision of the city's future. "If it would be up to me to plan it, I would try and convince people that it be (a) bigger project than it is now," he says, "bigger in the sense it should be more flexible for the future use . . . "
Pam Hoppes, Metro's right-of-way supervisor who has been involved in complex negotiations with property owners whose business were altered, destroyed or affected by the bus tunnel, recalls an early meeting with Khazak. "He looked at me," and asked, 'Why are we building only one tunnel?' " she says. " 'Why don't we drill two on top of each and move the Alaskan Way Viaduct under the bus tunnel?'
"And I thought, 'I love this guy.' "
Every other weekend, Khazak takes his 8-year-old daughter on a tour of the tunnel project. It has consumed much of his life the past two years. "It's much more than a job, " he says. "It's very big part of your life. I spend with this job more time than I spend with my family."
Khazak has become attached to this area. There are friends here. There are roots. Perhaps not as deep as those he dug up when he left the Soviet Union, but it would not be easy to leave.
"As a good project manager, I will tell you that everything is negotiable," he says when asked if he would leave Seattle for another job when the tunnel project is finished. He looks out the window at the city below.
"I'm doing this because I like to do it, because I know how to do it, and because I'm paid to do it," he says after a while. "And if I do it really well, and people think that I do it really well, then I want them to allow me to do bigger and better things."
wj
Labels:
James Wallace,
Russia,
Seattle,
tunnel,
Vladimir Khazak
Sunday, January 20, 2008
April 15, 2007 Los Angeles, How to fix traffic
How to fix traffic (LA Times)
Six specialists suggest quick and inexpensive ways to reduce traffic in Los Angeles.
April 15, 2007
With the city considering converting Pico and Olympic boulevards into one-way streets, Opinion asked six experts for other quick and inexpensive ways to reduce traffic in Los Angeles.
End the MTA's monopoly
By James E. Moore II, director of the transportation engineering program at USC.
The first step is to end the Metropolitan Transportation Authority's virtual monopoly and allow private jitney and bus operators to enter the transportation market to compete with the MTA and with each other. Taxi cabs introduce only a small degree of competition because local authorities keep fleets small.
Transit entrepreneurs who get 100% of their revenues from fares (unlike the MTA, which is heavily subsidized by taxpayers) would quickly figure out what kinds of services would attract car drivers. Unfortunately, any entrepreneurs who dare to try right now would be prosecuted for defying the MTA's state-sanctioned monopoly.
That's ridiculous. It would cost nothing to end the monopoly and allow independent jitney services to freely enter the transit market. The result would be a burst of new travel options and fewer cars on the street with one occupant.
Increase parking meter rates
By Donald Shoup, a professor of urban planning at the UCLA School of Public Affairs and , is the author of "The High Cost of Free Parking."
A surprising amount of traffic isn't caused by people on their way somewhere. Rather, it is caused by drivers who clog the streets while searching for parking spaces. For instance, about 8,000 cars a day park at the 470 meters in Westwood Village, so even a small amount of cruising time for each car adds up to a lot of traffic. Over a year, this cruising amounts to about 950,000 miles of travel -- the equivalent of 38 trips around the Earth.
And here's an inconvenient truth: Those 950,000 miles waste 47,000 gallons of gas and produces 730 tons of the carbon dioxide in one small business district.
What causes this astonishing waste? The fact that an hour at the meter costs 50 cents -- only 20% of the price for off-street parking, so drivers have a strong incentive to cruise.
Some cities adjust their meter rates to eliminate the incentive to cruise for parking. For instance, Redwood City, Calif., sets its downtown meter rates to achieve an 85% occupancy rate for curb parking. The price is 75 cents an hour at the center of downtown, and less elsewhere. Drivers can usually find a vacant space near their destinations because the vacancy rate is about 15% elsewhere, and the cruising time is near zero.
The added revenue totals $1 million a year, and Redwood City uses it to pay for more police and cleaner sidewalks in the metered downtown district.
If Los Angeles wants to reduce traffic congestion, -- as well as lower greenhouse-gas emissions -- and do it all quickly it should charge the right price for curb parking and spend the new revenue for public services in the metered neighborhoods.
Make the bus system easier
By Joel Kotkin, Irvine fellow with the New America Foundation and author of "The City: A Global History."
We unwisely keep trying to connect self-sufficient parts of the city through long-distance corridors. The proposal to turning Olympic and Pico Boulevards into one-way streets is yet another example of this foolish policy. Such a conversion would basically kill retail in such affected areas as Pico-Union and Pico-Robertson and work against any attempt to capitalize on their densities by attracting mix-use developments. Just look at what happened when some downtown streets were made one-way: Retail development catering to pedestrians has been a hard sell.
What Los Angeles needs is a transit system that better reflects what it is -- a sprawling mid-density city. So build the world's easiest-to-use bus system. This network should expand such transit innovations as the MTA's Metro Rapid buses, which run in dedicated lanes, and Rapid Express buses, which make few stops. These systems are far less expensive to build than light rail or a "subway to the sea."
We also should synchronize more traffic lights, fix more potholes and -- most important -- build "village centers" in neighborhoods so people do not have to make as many trips across town. Lowering city taxes on home-based businesses, which would encourage their creation, would facilitate this transition.
Finally, we need to think about building toll lanes, or tollways, to divert the truck traffic that grinds through the city. The 110 and 710 corridors to the ports are obvious candidates for such lanes. This should be a win-win all around: safer freeways because of fewer trucks, quicker trips for trucks, and decreased pollution because trucks would idle less.
Make connections
By Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris, a professor and chairwoman of the UCLA Department of Urban Planning.
Our traffic nightmare didn't spring up overnight, nor can commuters expect an easy, quick fix. It will take coordinated efforts on the part of city officials, transportation planners and engineers, employers and commuters. Short term, these ideas, collectively implemented, could ease traffic congestion:
Make bus rides faster by creating dedicated bus lanes on the 10, 101 and 405 freeways and expand the MTA's Metro Rapid bus system to connect such major employment centers as downtown, the Wilshire corridor, LAX, UCLA, USC and the South Bay.
Connect subway, rail and bus stations to outlying neighborhoods through shuttles or the DASH system.
To improve traffic flow, synchronize more traffic signals; make some major thoroughfares one-way; minimize left-turn opportunities during rush hours; use side streets for access to parking lots connected to retail outlets.
In the long run, if more employers offered workers variable work schedules and rewarded those who used mass transit instead of company-subsidized parking, rush-hour congestion would significantly lessen.
Turn carpool lanes into toll lanes
By Ted Balaker, Jacobs fellow at the Reason Foundation.
A big roadblock to faster traffic flow is the now-outdated notion that carpool lanes, or high-occupancy vehicle lanes, are good congestion-busters. For the most part, they're not. Carpool commuting is becoming less common even as more lanes to accommodate it are being built. Better that we turn these carpool lanes into special toll lanes.
The toll would go up or down depending on the flow of cars: The greater the congestion, the more expensive to use these high-occupancy-toll lanes, or HOT lanes. But the flexible-pricing system would maintain free-flow conditions, allowing more vehicles to fly along the same lanes that today are often as congested as the regular ones.
Apart from buying special software and hiring some back-office staff, setting up HOT lanes would be simply a matter of installing antennas for communication with electronic toll collectors, video cameras to catch cheaters, changeable message signs at various points along the route and plastic pylons to separate the lanes from the regular ones.
Transit buses also could use the special lanes, creating the virtual equivalent of an exclusive busway (think the Valley's Orange Line), but at the fraction of the cost because there is no need to build facilities from scratch. The Bay Area plans to develop a regionwide network of HOT lanes. Because L.A. is home to the nation's most extensive carpool-lane network, it would seem a natural for conversion to a HOT system.
Cut bus fares to boost ridership
By Joel R. Reynolds, senior attorney and director of the Natural Resources Defense Council's urban program.
For starters, we need a fast but comprehensive analysis of which short-term measures could reduce congestion in Los Angeles now, including new incentives for carpooling and telecommuting, This could be undertaken by city or county transportation staff, a committee appointed by the mayor or an independent research institution. But it must be done immediately.
Second, we need to strengthen the city's only widely used rapid transit system -- buses -- by making it easier, faster, cheaper and more reliable to use than a car. The would require more buses and Rapid Express bus-only lanes should be established on as many major city arteries -- both east-west and north-south -- as possible, including Wilshire Boulevard.
Instead of increasing bus fares, as the Metropolitan Transportation Authority has proposed, we should freeze or cut them to attract even more riders. To pay for this, new capital projects should be deferred and subsidies allocated to keep bus fares affordable.
Long-term transportation planning is essential, but the MTA must not be allowed to starve its bus system to feed a future rail system. And reasonable alternatives to the subway, such as a monorail system that may be both cheaper and quicker to build, should not be dismissed out of hand.
Hit drivers in the pocketbook
By Brian D. Taylor, associate professor of drban planning and director of the Institute of Transportation Studies at UCLA
It's important to understand that L.A. is not congested because it has more roads than most U.S. cities (it doesn't) or because people drive more here than most other places (they don't). L.A. is congested, and getting more so over time, because development densities here are high and increasing, while most people get around in cars. Continued growth will only worsen the situation, and improved public transit – while desirable on many grounds – won't reduce traffic. Worldwide, congestion is endemic in cities with the highest levels of transit use. While public transit can prove an attractive alternative to sitting in traffic, transit systems actually depend on slow-moving traffic and high parking prices to effectively compete with automobiles for customers.
The cold, hard truth is that there are only three ways to truly "solve gridlock," and none is popular. First, we could substantially increase road supply by spending tens of billions to blanket the southland with so many new roads that every conceivable vehicle trip could be accommodated during rush hour. Second, we could drastically reduce travel demand via a severe economic downturn, catastrophic disaster, or prohibitions on driving that would empty our region of millions of residents and thousands of firms so that those who remain behind could travel freely. Most of us would agree that neither of these rather extreme options is desirable.
The third way is to bring road supply and travel demand into balance with prices. So instead of paying for transportation as we do now with bonds, sales taxes, fuel taxes, and the like, drivers would instead pay as they go -- they would pay dearly to travel at rush hour in congested areas, and much less at other times and on other routes. While common sense tells us that millions of trips would have to be priced off of the roads before traffic would move freely, common sense in this case is wrong. When it comes to traffic, small price changes can make a big difference.
So why would pricing road use reduce congestion so much more than, say, one-way streets or a subway to the sea? Because added road or transit capacity that reduces delay in the short term, encourages additional vehicle trips on newly (and temporarily) uncongested roads over the longer term. Pricing, on the other hand, replaces one cost (time spent sitting in traffic) with another (tolls paid to travel freely during rush hour). But while spending time in traffic produces no revenue, spending on tolls generates a lot of money to improve highway and transit systems directly from those who benefit most from road use (instead of, for example, our current transportation sales taxes that disproportionately burden the poor).
While pricing roads is the only reasonable path to a far less congested Los Angeles, the idea remains wildly unpopular among voters and the people whom they elect. Fair enough, but we then need to be honest in acknowledging that our current efforts to reduce congestion will at best slow its inexorable rise. If L.A. is to continue growing, Angelenos do have a choice: They can pay more time in traffic delays on free roads, or they can pay more in tolls to avoid traffic. But either way, it's gonna cost them.
Related articles
Market-Based Transportation Alternatives For Los Angeles
Six specialists suggest quick and inexpensive ways to reduce traffic in Los Angeles.
April 15, 2007
With the city considering converting Pico and Olympic boulevards into one-way streets, Opinion asked six experts for other quick and inexpensive ways to reduce traffic in Los Angeles.
End the MTA's monopoly
By James E. Moore II, director of the transportation engineering program at USC.
The first step is to end the Metropolitan Transportation Authority's virtual monopoly and allow private jitney and bus operators to enter the transportation market to compete with the MTA and with each other. Taxi cabs introduce only a small degree of competition because local authorities keep fleets small.
Transit entrepreneurs who get 100% of their revenues from fares (unlike the MTA, which is heavily subsidized by taxpayers) would quickly figure out what kinds of services would attract car drivers. Unfortunately, any entrepreneurs who dare to try right now would be prosecuted for defying the MTA's state-sanctioned monopoly.
That's ridiculous. It would cost nothing to end the monopoly and allow independent jitney services to freely enter the transit market. The result would be a burst of new travel options and fewer cars on the street with one occupant.
Increase parking meter rates
By Donald Shoup, a professor of urban planning at the UCLA School of Public Affairs and , is the author of "The High Cost of Free Parking."
A surprising amount of traffic isn't caused by people on their way somewhere. Rather, it is caused by drivers who clog the streets while searching for parking spaces. For instance, about 8,000 cars a day park at the 470 meters in Westwood Village, so even a small amount of cruising time for each car adds up to a lot of traffic. Over a year, this cruising amounts to about 950,000 miles of travel -- the equivalent of 38 trips around the Earth.
And here's an inconvenient truth: Those 950,000 miles waste 47,000 gallons of gas and produces 730 tons of the carbon dioxide in one small business district.
What causes this astonishing waste? The fact that an hour at the meter costs 50 cents -- only 20% of the price for off-street parking, so drivers have a strong incentive to cruise.
Some cities adjust their meter rates to eliminate the incentive to cruise for parking. For instance, Redwood City, Calif., sets its downtown meter rates to achieve an 85% occupancy rate for curb parking. The price is 75 cents an hour at the center of downtown, and less elsewhere. Drivers can usually find a vacant space near their destinations because the vacancy rate is about 15% elsewhere, and the cruising time is near zero.
The added revenue totals $1 million a year, and Redwood City uses it to pay for more police and cleaner sidewalks in the metered downtown district.
If Los Angeles wants to reduce traffic congestion, -- as well as lower greenhouse-gas emissions -- and do it all quickly it should charge the right price for curb parking and spend the new revenue for public services in the metered neighborhoods.
Make the bus system easier
By Joel Kotkin, Irvine fellow with the New America Foundation and author of "The City: A Global History."
We unwisely keep trying to connect self-sufficient parts of the city through long-distance corridors. The proposal to turning Olympic and Pico Boulevards into one-way streets is yet another example of this foolish policy. Such a conversion would basically kill retail in such affected areas as Pico-Union and Pico-Robertson and work against any attempt to capitalize on their densities by attracting mix-use developments. Just look at what happened when some downtown streets were made one-way: Retail development catering to pedestrians has been a hard sell.
What Los Angeles needs is a transit system that better reflects what it is -- a sprawling mid-density city. So build the world's easiest-to-use bus system. This network should expand such transit innovations as the MTA's Metro Rapid buses, which run in dedicated lanes, and Rapid Express buses, which make few stops. These systems are far less expensive to build than light rail or a "subway to the sea."
We also should synchronize more traffic lights, fix more potholes and -- most important -- build "village centers" in neighborhoods so people do not have to make as many trips across town. Lowering city taxes on home-based businesses, which would encourage their creation, would facilitate this transition.
Finally, we need to think about building toll lanes, or tollways, to divert the truck traffic that grinds through the city. The 110 and 710 corridors to the ports are obvious candidates for such lanes. This should be a win-win all around: safer freeways because of fewer trucks, quicker trips for trucks, and decreased pollution because trucks would idle less.
Make connections
By Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris, a professor and chairwoman of the UCLA Department of Urban Planning.
Our traffic nightmare didn't spring up overnight, nor can commuters expect an easy, quick fix. It will take coordinated efforts on the part of city officials, transportation planners and engineers, employers and commuters. Short term, these ideas, collectively implemented, could ease traffic congestion:
Make bus rides faster by creating dedicated bus lanes on the 10, 101 and 405 freeways and expand the MTA's Metro Rapid bus system to connect such major employment centers as downtown, the Wilshire corridor, LAX, UCLA, USC and the South Bay.
Connect subway, rail and bus stations to outlying neighborhoods through shuttles or the DASH system.
To improve traffic flow, synchronize more traffic signals; make some major thoroughfares one-way; minimize left-turn opportunities during rush hours; use side streets for access to parking lots connected to retail outlets.
In the long run, if more employers offered workers variable work schedules and rewarded those who used mass transit instead of company-subsidized parking, rush-hour congestion would significantly lessen.
Turn carpool lanes into toll lanes
By Ted Balaker, Jacobs fellow at the Reason Foundation.
A big roadblock to faster traffic flow is the now-outdated notion that carpool lanes, or high-occupancy vehicle lanes, are good congestion-busters. For the most part, they're not. Carpool commuting is becoming less common even as more lanes to accommodate it are being built. Better that we turn these carpool lanes into special toll lanes.
The toll would go up or down depending on the flow of cars: The greater the congestion, the more expensive to use these high-occupancy-toll lanes, or HOT lanes. But the flexible-pricing system would maintain free-flow conditions, allowing more vehicles to fly along the same lanes that today are often as congested as the regular ones.
Apart from buying special software and hiring some back-office staff, setting up HOT lanes would be simply a matter of installing antennas for communication with electronic toll collectors, video cameras to catch cheaters, changeable message signs at various points along the route and plastic pylons to separate the lanes from the regular ones.
Transit buses also could use the special lanes, creating the virtual equivalent of an exclusive busway (think the Valley's Orange Line), but at the fraction of the cost because there is no need to build facilities from scratch. The Bay Area plans to develop a regionwide network of HOT lanes. Because L.A. is home to the nation's most extensive carpool-lane network, it would seem a natural for conversion to a HOT system.
Cut bus fares to boost ridership
By Joel R. Reynolds, senior attorney and director of the Natural Resources Defense Council's urban program.
For starters, we need a fast but comprehensive analysis of which short-term measures could reduce congestion in Los Angeles now, including new incentives for carpooling and telecommuting, This could be undertaken by city or county transportation staff, a committee appointed by the mayor or an independent research institution. But it must be done immediately.
Second, we need to strengthen the city's only widely used rapid transit system -- buses -- by making it easier, faster, cheaper and more reliable to use than a car. The would require more buses and Rapid Express bus-only lanes should be established on as many major city arteries -- both east-west and north-south -- as possible, including Wilshire Boulevard.
Instead of increasing bus fares, as the Metropolitan Transportation Authority has proposed, we should freeze or cut them to attract even more riders. To pay for this, new capital projects should be deferred and subsidies allocated to keep bus fares affordable.
Long-term transportation planning is essential, but the MTA must not be allowed to starve its bus system to feed a future rail system. And reasonable alternatives to the subway, such as a monorail system that may be both cheaper and quicker to build, should not be dismissed out of hand.
Hit drivers in the pocketbook
By Brian D. Taylor, associate professor of drban planning and director of the Institute of Transportation Studies at UCLA
It's important to understand that L.A. is not congested because it has more roads than most U.S. cities (it doesn't) or because people drive more here than most other places (they don't). L.A. is congested, and getting more so over time, because development densities here are high and increasing, while most people get around in cars. Continued growth will only worsen the situation, and improved public transit – while desirable on many grounds – won't reduce traffic. Worldwide, congestion is endemic in cities with the highest levels of transit use. While public transit can prove an attractive alternative to sitting in traffic, transit systems actually depend on slow-moving traffic and high parking prices to effectively compete with automobiles for customers.
The cold, hard truth is that there are only three ways to truly "solve gridlock," and none is popular. First, we could substantially increase road supply by spending tens of billions to blanket the southland with so many new roads that every conceivable vehicle trip could be accommodated during rush hour. Second, we could drastically reduce travel demand via a severe economic downturn, catastrophic disaster, or prohibitions on driving that would empty our region of millions of residents and thousands of firms so that those who remain behind could travel freely. Most of us would agree that neither of these rather extreme options is desirable.
The third way is to bring road supply and travel demand into balance with prices. So instead of paying for transportation as we do now with bonds, sales taxes, fuel taxes, and the like, drivers would instead pay as they go -- they would pay dearly to travel at rush hour in congested areas, and much less at other times and on other routes. While common sense tells us that millions of trips would have to be priced off of the roads before traffic would move freely, common sense in this case is wrong. When it comes to traffic, small price changes can make a big difference.
So why would pricing road use reduce congestion so much more than, say, one-way streets or a subway to the sea? Because added road or transit capacity that reduces delay in the short term, encourages additional vehicle trips on newly (and temporarily) uncongested roads over the longer term. Pricing, on the other hand, replaces one cost (time spent sitting in traffic) with another (tolls paid to travel freely during rush hour). But while spending time in traffic produces no revenue, spending on tolls generates a lot of money to improve highway and transit systems directly from those who benefit most from road use (instead of, for example, our current transportation sales taxes that disproportionately burden the poor).
While pricing roads is the only reasonable path to a far less congested Los Angeles, the idea remains wildly unpopular among voters and the people whom they elect. Fair enough, but we then need to be honest in acknowledging that our current efforts to reduce congestion will at best slow its inexorable rise. If L.A. is to continue growing, Angelenos do have a choice: They can pay more time in traffic delays on free roads, or they can pay more in tolls to avoid traffic. But either way, it's gonna cost them.
Related articles
Market-Based Transportation Alternatives For Los Angeles
Labels:
James Moore,
Joel Kotkin,
Los Angeles,
traffic congestion
Monday, December 10, 2007
August 2007 Lessons of Boston’s Big Dig
Lessons of Boston’s Big Dig
Nicole Gelinas, City Journal (article)
America’s most ambitious infrastructure project inspired engineering marvels—and colossal mismanagement.
States, cities, and towns across America must spend hundreds of billions of dollars annually to preserve the nation’s infrastructure—the backbone of its private-sector economy—and yet more to build the next generation of roads, bridges, tunnels, and dams. Spending so much money wisely is daunting. The good news: no matter how complex and expensive any future project is, it’s unlikely to be more so than the Big Dig, Massachusetts’s three-decade-long quest to bury and expand the Central Artery, Boston’s major interstate highway, and carve out a new underwater tunnel to Logan Airport.
Conceived in the 1970s and finished, more or less, in 2005, the Big Dig is modern America’s most ambitious urban-infrastructure project, spanning six presidents and seven governors, costing $14.8 billion, and featuring many never-before-done engineering and construction marvels. Long before construction peaked around the turn of the millennium, eating up $100 million a month for three years, the Big Dig was a local legend, spawning dozens of jokes. (Wouldn’t it be cheaper to raise Boston than to bury the highway? Congressman Barney Frank asked.) Later, when fewer people viewed the Dig whimsically, it was the setting of a 2002 murder-mystery novel. And last year, after falling concrete panels in a Big Dig tunnel that had been open for three years killed a 38-year-old car passenger, the project became a reminder that infrastructure failure can exact a cruel price.
Every major decision that could conceivably be made on an infrastructure project was made on the Big Dig, from how to pay for it to how to forge the public and political support for it to how to manage its construction and maintenance. Its stewards have encountered every imaginable public-infrastructure pitfall, and fallen into many. The Big Dig’s story is an invaluable lesson: How can America invest in infrastructure—and do it smart?
The reasons for the Big Dig date back nearly 80 years. In 1930, a city planning board noted that Boston’s “street system should be adapted to the requirements of the motor age” and proposed an elevated expressway. The Central Artery’s first planners acknowledged that “the erection of . . . elevated structures . . . in downtown Boston” would hurt some residents’ quality of life. But a “vehicular subway”—the first mention of the idea that, half a century later, would become the Big Dig—“would interfere with sewers and with . . . rapid transit subways.” The state and city had the luxury of deciding to build an elevated highway because bottom-up, Jane Jacobs–inspired urban coalitions didn’t exist yet to thwart the era’s top-down, Robert Moses–style urban planners.
The Great Depression and the Second World War temporarily interfered with the idea. By the late 1940s, Boston still didn’t have its highway, despite two decades of planning—and despite the increasing need for fast access to the city, which was hemorrhaging jobs to the suburbs. But in 1949, six years before Congress and President Eisenhower funded the Interstate Highway System, Massachusetts started building the hideous green steel Central Artery that would scar Boston, physically and psychologically, for the rest of the century. “Boston was a pioneer, but this was bad pioneering,” says Rick Dimino, former city transportation commissioner and today president of the business group A Better City.
It’s easy to follow officials’ reasoning for building the Artery along Boston’s waterfront. That’s where Boston’s business district, once centered on shipping, was located, after all. But the Artery vivisected Boston. It barred pedestrians from the water. It overwhelmed low-rise streets, a historic outdoor fruit and vegetable market, and even the historic Faneuil Hall with traffic, noise, and shadow. It erased swaths of the working-class Italian North End, displacing 573 businesses—mostly small shops and trading firms—and hundreds of families. Owners of some buildings that escaped the bulldozers bricked over windows that faced the Artery. Boston understood the Artery’s impact so quickly that in 1954 it changed tack and buried a last stretch in a tunnel.
Though it did enable suburban workers to get to new office jobs, the Artery quickly became obsolete. Its intended daily capacity was 70,000 cars, but it soon groaned under 170,000. Poorly designed and constructed, it had structural problems and an accident rate four times the national average, because drivers veering toward the Artery’s abundance of downtown exits collided with drivers continuing to the increasingly busy Logan Airport. The building of the Artery turned Bostonians so vehemently against highways that the state halted their construction in the early seventies, killing a planned inner belt that, after displacing another 4,000 families, would have carried traffic from the downtown Artery to other parts of the city. But because the belt and the Artery had been conceived as an integrated system, Artery traffic had nowhere to go. Little more than a decade after the Artery opened, Massachusetts and Boston started scheming to junk it.
When Governor Michael Dukakis’s administration started thinking about fixing this mess in the seventies and early eighties, it had learned the lessons of the Artery’s construction well. But how to fix the Artery, and heal the downtown neighborhoods that it sliced through, without uprooting more residents and slapping a “closed for construction” sign on Boston? How to ease traffic by building an airport tunnel that, unlike the two existing tunnels, would bypass downtown, when the politically powerful neighborhood near the airport opposed new traffic and the seizing of homes?
If Robert Moses and Jane Jacobs had a child, it might have been Fred Salvucci, Dukakis’s transportation secretary, who concocted the Big Dig project. Armed with two MIT engineering degrees, Salvucci had fought the inner belt from city hall before joining Dukakis; he even had firsthand experience of how highway construction affects cities, having seen the state seize and raze his elderly grandmother’s house to make way for a road. Salvucci remembers persuading Dukakis to support the Big Dig by making two crucial pledges: “It would enhance the urban environment rather than degrade it, and there would be no taking of housing.” The state then won the public over by mollifying anyone, anywhere, who had anything at all to do with the project. “We learned from Westway,” says Salvucci, referring to New York’s plan to depress its West Side Highway, which failed because the city didn’t garner various interest groups’ support before seeking congressional approval.
Massachusetts’s task was partly northeastern politics as usual. Unions knew that they’d benefit from a “project labor agreement,” through which their workers would agree not to strike if contractors, even nonunion ones, would hire through union halls. Police officers would get tens of millions of dollars annually in overtime, since local law mandates that a policeman watch over any work site. Minority-group reps were pleased with a pledge to hire blacks and women for construction jobs.
But the state had a new task, one that would become a feature of big infrastructure projects nationwide: “mitigation.” Broadly speaking, mitigation was the state’s promise to alleviate the Big Dig’s impact on Boston, from interrupting business to harming the environment. Mitigation eventually accounted for about one-third of the Big Dig’s cost—from the thousands of dollars needed to outfit North End apartments with air conditioning, soundproof windows, and firm mattresses as residents settled in for a decade of construction to the more than $1 billion needed to rework a planned bridge that business leaders, residents, and the nearby city of Cambridge considered ugly.
Mitigation made downtown businesses happy, promising not to shut down any of the Central Artery’s six lanes during construction, and promising further that companies such as Fidelity Investments wouldn’t lack electricity or telephones for even a few hours as contractors dug up miles of utilities to make room for underground highways. Mitigation made Gillette, Boston’s biggest manufacturer, happy, working with the company to marry its complicated underwater infrastructure to the Big Dig’s. Mitigation made the post office happy, building temporary roads to a distribution station. Mitigation made airport neighbors happy, vowing that cars from the airport tunnel wouldn’t exit onto residential land. Mitigation also made environmentalists happy with its promise to preserve as open space three-quarters of the land that the Artery’s demolition would create (the highway tunnels that would run underneath couldn’t support heavy construction, anyway). It made more ambitious environmentalists happy, promising to improve mass transit and to use some of the excavated dirt—which, because it had saltwater in it, couldn’t be dumped inland—to transform a Boston Harbor island from a noxious landfill into a beachfront park. It made archaeologists happy, paying to catalog artifacts dating back to colonial days. It didn’t make rats happy: after near-hysteria that construction would unleash vermin whose underground lairs also dated to colonial days, the project launched an aggressive rodent-control program.
The mitigation, some of which was sensible, tempered even reasonable criticism of the Big Dig. Few locals voiced skepticism during planning. Once you got your own interest protected, you kept quiet, to make sure that the project, free of local opposition, would win federal funding. Thanks largely to mitigation efforts, more than 80 percent of Boston residents and nearly two-thirds of state residents supported the Big Dig in its early years.
Mitigation notwithstanding, the Big Dig still would probably be a near-forgotten dream like Westway if not for Massachusetts’s Washington dominance in the late seventies and eighties. Democrats ran Capitol Hill, and Massachusetts’s wholly Democratic congressional delegation had a lot of seniority. Everyone in Massachusetts thus assumed that they would fund the project with “ten-cent dollars,” of which the feds would pay the other 90.
Even so, Massachusetts got its initial federal funding only because of Salvucci’s and Dukakis’s brilliant and successful argument: since it had built its Artery before the Interstate Highway System paid for such projects, the state should be able to use the federal money that it hadn’t spent back then to rebuild the Artery. This fluke explains why Massachusetts, at a time when other northeastern states were ignoring infrastructure in favor of expanding social programs like Med-icaid, focused on nuts and bolts: it knew that if it did so, it could tap into “free” federal money. Taking this argument to Washington, legendary Massachusetts Democrat Tip O’Neill, the House’s majority leader and soon to be its Speaker, in 1976 inserted “placeholder” funds for the Big Dig into a congressional blueprint of costs to complete the Interstate Highway System.
A decade later, though, President Reagan didn’t care to give Massachusetts Democrats billions for what skeptics considered a “highway beautification project.” When Reagan vetoed a 1987 highway bill that contained the Big Dig’s first significant federal funding, the real politics started. Tip, and Ted Kennedy in the Senate, garnered enough supporters, including 13 Republicans, for an override. In a preview of how Washington would work over the next two decades, they approved goodies that other states wanted, too. Wavering out-of-state politicians came on board.
After Tip’s override, local Big Dig planners never worried about pesky things like whether cost estimates and project scope were reasonable. Massachusetts had proved that it was more powerful than the president; surely there would always be more money where its initial funding came from. But over the ensuing decades, the Big Dig’s price tag waxed and Massachusetts’s congressional power waned. Washington imposed a firm dollar cap on its Big Dig spending at the turn of the millennium, leaving Massachusetts to pay the rest. State taxpayers would eventually foot nearly half the project’s cost.
The Bay State’s experience is a lesson for state officials: the clout you have today may be gone tomorrow. If you think that an ambitious project’s benefits exceed its costs, convince your taxpayers up front—rather than getting Washington, which may change its mind down the road, to get its taxpayers to pay.
In retrospect, it’s amazing how much went right after construction started in 1991. Over 14 years, Massachusetts, its consultants, and its contractors carved canyons under Boston while the city hummed above. They designed and built seven and a half miles of highway—161 miles of separate lanes—more than half of them in tunnels. They built six interchanges and 200 bridges.
One of the innovations that made this work possible was the slurry wall, also used at New York’s World Trade Center, which allowed the state, as Salvucci puts it, to build huge underground tunnels “arthroscopically,” without pockmarking Boston with huge uncovered holes. The slurry wall, in effect, let Boston dig itself up without shutting itself down. The Big Dig’s general reliance on new technology was a major factor in one of the project officials’ biggest decisions: choosing a consortium made up of Bechtel and Parsons Brinckerhoff as the “management consultant.” Parsons was an expert in innovative urban tunneling dating to the early twentieth century, when it built New York City’s subways. Bechtel had constructed the Hoover Dam as well as most of modern Saudi Arabia, and had fabled political connections to accompany its engineering and logistics mystique. Caspar Weinberger and George Shultz, both in Reagan’s cabinet, were Bechtel men—though that connection hadn’t helped Salvucci at veto time.
One of the creative, audacious, and potentially disastrous things that Bechtel and Parsons, as well as the state’s contractors, did right on the Big Dig was jacking up the Central Artery—replacing the half-million-ton highway’s 69 support columns with temporary “underpinnings” so that contractors could remove the columns and make way for the tunnels. “Pinning the Artery” wasn’t the Big Dig’s only never-before-done feat. The striking Zakim Bridge—the one redesigned after community outrage—is the world’s widest cable-stayed asymmetrical bridge, expanding from eight lanes to ten to account for complicated traffic flow.
Elsewhere, underneath active railroad tracks, engineers froze ground too soft to withstand construction and pushed prebuilt tunnel sections through. They erected a huge temporary dam to dry out a basin in which to construct tunnel segments—and then flooded the basin, floating the segments and resinking them in their new underwater homes. They built underground bridges to hold up subways, threading highway tunnels above and below mass transit. And though insurance tables had predicted 40 serious accidents during the project, the Big Dig suffered only a quarter of that total, and three construction deaths—showing how much things had changed since, say, the 1870s, when raising the Brooklyn Bridge took 27 lives.
Leave it to Massachusetts, though, to turn the Big Dig’s reputation from resounding success to humiliating failure—first in terms of the project’s cost. From day one—even after accounting for politicians’ erring on the low side to gain public approval—the Big Dig was fated to cost more than its 1982 price tag of $2.6 billion.
That number didn’t include much of the project’s mitigation, including big changes like the billion-plus extra to remake the Zakim Bridge. Nor did it include the real costs of staying on schedule. The Big Dig often let its contractors start work on pieces of the project before designs for other key parts were complete. This approach—part of the project’s philosophy of getting things done now and asking questions later—meant expensive changes to contracts. By the early 1990s, as the state added new work, and as its consultants and contractors looked underground to see what was actually there, the Big Dig’s price tag had ballooned to nearly $8 billion.
True, critics aren’t being entirely fair when they compare the project’s final cost, $14.8 billion, with the initial estimate; $2.6 billion in 1982 is $5.6 billion today, thanks to inflation. And inflation has similarly distorted the cost of the many expensive changes made to the project—because the more realistic cost estimates that accounted for those changes were also calculated in then-current dollars, rather than in the dollars that the state eventually had to pay. Still, there’s a lesson here for managers of other infrastructure projects: be careful with that first number, because it can become a permanent benchmark against which to measure success or failure.
Perhaps it’s understandable that inflation and massive increases in scope would swell the project’s price tag. But the Big Dig’s planners truly failed the public through a deliberate decision: for years, they used dubious accounting methods that hid true costs.
In 1994, two years into construction, Bechtel and Parsons officials compiled convincing evidence that the Big Dig would cost nearly $14 billion in completion-year dollars—far more than public officials were disclosing—and took their findings to the state, says former state inspector general Bob Cerasoli, who supervised a 2001 report on the Big Dig’s finances. But the state didn’t tell the public, so alarming Bechtel that its president flew to Boston to see then-governor William Weld. Afterward, according to Cerasoli’s report, “state managers directed state and [Bechtel and Parsons] staff to . . . maintain the fiction of an . . . $8 billion project. . . . They did so by applying a largely semantic series of exclusions, deductions, and accounting assumptions that covered up the $6 billion difference,” often with the knowledge of federal highway officials.
Some state officials thought that if they delayed disclosing money woes, the public would be so thrilled with early improvements like the Ted Williams Tunnel, which opened in 1995, that they wouldn’t pay attention to boring finances. But as an internal “pros and cons” document noted, if the state didn’t inform bondholders, it risked fraud charges—and, in fact, federal securities regulators later reprimanded Weld’s Big Dig boss, James Kerasiotes, for “misleading” investors. Even more pressing, the state needed actual money to continue its project, so it had to come clean despite worries that “we could become the central controversy of the next year in Massachusetts.” It was after the state finally fessed up that the feds imposed their permanent funding cap on the project.
Massachusetts’s desire to insulate the public from the Big Dig’s costs also led to a fateful decision by Governor Weld. Weld needed a ready source of money for the project, without hiking taxes or cutting spending elsewhere. So he transferred the Big Dig’s assets to the Massachusetts Turnpike Authority, an unaccountable public entity akin to New York’s Metropolitan Transportation Authority, in return for some of the authority’s future toll revenue, which would back Big Dig bonds. This costly trade added a new layer of bureaucracy to the project, which needed, more than anything, one elected person to be ultimately accountable. After last year’s fatal ceiling collapse, Mitt Romney, governor for nearly four years, could point to the fact that his predecessor’s appointee still ran the Big Dig.
But the Big Dig’s biggest pitfall was that Massachusetts never understood a basic fact: that it couldn’t pay someone else to assume its own responsibility for an immensely complex, risky project. As the National Transportation Safety Board (NTSB) would later say in its report on the 2006 ceiling collapse, Bechtel and Parsons, the state’s long-term consultants, were “performing the role that would normally be carried out by a government agency, specifically, the state highway department.”
Since costs turned the Big Dig into a scandal, the public has often seen Bechtel and Parsons as its villains. The perception in Massachusetts—never dispelled by state officials—is that the duo’s thousand-plus white-collar workers, dwarfing their few dozen public-sector counterparts, ran the Big Dig, expertly controlling and manipulating designers, contractors, and information, without letting anyone else have much say, from colleagues at lowly engineering firms to meddling public officials. But even assuming the worst—and the reality is more complicated—people usually can’t manipulate you unless you let them. As early as 1991, the state’s inspector general warned of the “increasingly apparent vulnerabilities . . . of [Massachusetts’s] long-term dependence on a consultant” whose contract had an “open-ended structure” and “inadequate monitoring.” The main deficiency, as later IG reports detailed, was that Bechtel and Parsons—as “preliminary designer,” “design coordinator,” “construction coordinator,” and “contract administrator”—were often in charge of checking their own work. If, say, the team noticed in managing construction that a contract was over budget because of problems rooted in preliminary design, it didn’t have much incentive to speak up.
The state should also have known that when consultancy work will last years and when consultants plan to introduce technologies so sophisticated that they can overwhelm the state’s ability to oversee them, the state’s going to wind up in a vulnerable position. Massachusetts would have been smart to introduce some checks and balances early on—perhaps splitting the work that Bechtel and Parsons were doing into smaller parts, having separate consultants for preliminary design and for “project management” work, or keeping some of the “management” in house. Instead, in the name of cost efficiencies, the state further blurred the distinction between public and private sectors by folding Bechtel and Parsons employees and its own workers into one “integrated project organization” in 1998. And though the state’s Massachusetts Turnpike Authority was at the top of the new organization chart—which was immensely complicated by multiple layers of theoretical oversight, including supervision from federal highway officials as well as the feds’ General Accounting Office—the state designated Bechtel and Parsons its “owner’s representative” in some areas, complicating even further the answer to the straightforward question: Who was in charge?
Massachusetts’s laissez-faire attitude followed from a fundamental misapprehension: that Bechtel and Parsons were their partners, not outside consultants, and were thus assuming some performance risk. In a 1994 interview, Kerasiotes, then the state’s transportation secretary, argued that Bechtel’s incentive to perform its job properly was its reputation: “Go to San Francisco, walk in the lobby” of Bechtel’s headquarters, he suggested. “What you’re going to see [are] prominent pictures of the Central Artery. . . . If they are causing this project to screw up, . . . they’re not going to market themselves that way.”
But Bechtel and Parsons never took on any performance risk—risk that the public sector carries as the ultimate funder and manager. If the project were an investment-banking deal, Bechtel would have been an advisor counseling a company on whether to undertake a merger, not an investor in that merger. “Our contractual responsibility as management consultant was to deliver a professional standard of care, not to guarantee the contractors’ work,” says Keith Sibley, Bechtel and Parsons’s longtime Big Dig director. It’s a crucial distinction: Bechtel and Parsons promised not perfect results but professional advisory and management work—and reasonable people may differ about what constitutes “professional.” It’s particularly difficult to assess decisions made under an “integrated project organization,” where everything is opaque about who was responsible for which decisions, or whether particular decisions were the result of public and private collaboration.
This problem of murky responsibility came up repeatedly during the Big Dig, but most tragically with the ceiling collapse. Designers engineered a lightweight ceiling for the tunnel in which Milena del Valle died. But Massachusetts, annoyed by cost overruns and cleanliness problems on a similar ceiling, and at the suggestion of federal highway officials, decided to fit the new tunnel with a cheaper ceiling, which turned out to be heavier. Realizing that hanging concrete where no built-in anchors existed to hold it would be a difficult job, the ceiling’s designer, a company called Gannett Fleming, called for contractors to install the ceiling with an unusually large built-in margin for extra weight. Shortly after contractors installed the ceiling—using anchors held by a high-strength epoxy, as Gannett specified—workers noticed that it was coming loose. Consultants and contractors decided to take it apart and reinstall it. Two years later, after a contractor told Bechtel that “several anchors appear to be pulling away from the concrete,” Bechtel directed it to “set new anchors and retest.” After the resetting and retesting, the tunnel opened to traffic, with fatal consequences.
In hindsight, they all did the wrong thing. The real problem was that the poorly labeled and poorly marketed “fast set” epoxy that the contractors used for the ceiling wasn’t suitable for long-term loads of any type: the company that made the glue, Powers Fasteners, didn’t warn clearly that the epoxy wasn’t interchangeable with another, suitable “standard set” epoxy that it made. The National Transportation Safety Board’s report noted the company’s failure, and Massachusetts has indicted Powers for criminal negligence. But the feds also mentioned that neither Gannett nor Bechtel and Parsons had thought about the ceiling’s long-term performance, when the earlier ceiling failures should have made it clear to both Bechtel and a construction contractor that reinstallation hadn’t worked. Finally, the report points out, once the tunnel opened in 2003, Massachusetts was supposed to conduct regular inspections, which likely would have revealed the ceiling panels’ obvious displacement well before the collapse.
Massachusetts, after taking a hands-off approach to its project’s risks during construction, is today using its most fearsome power—the power to indict—to push Bechtel and Parsons to settle with the state for hundreds of millions of dollars and avoid criminal charges. Massachusetts’s approach is a warning to future private-sector contractors and consultants: if something goes disastrously wrong with a project in which thousands of critical decisions were made with public and private cooperation, the state may use the criminal-justice system as a cudgel to deflect its own accountability.
Massachusetts might have avoided some problems by transferring certain Big Dig risks to the private sector through discrete, well-defined deals: signing a long-term contract with a firm to help build, operate, and maintain the Zakim Bridge, for instance. Such an endeavor, though, would have required aggressive public-sector management of initial costs, scope, and complex contract language—things the state hasn’t excelled at.
Any risk transfer, moreover, would have been limited. Massachusetts could never have turned over full technical, operational, and financial risks of the Big Dig to any reputable company or group. The project had too many unknowns. Smart, reputable companies don’t take unlimited risks at the behest of a fickle, indecisive client for a limited profit. The best thing Massachusetts could have done was to realize the project’s real risks so that it could manage them effectively.
Now Democratic governor Deval Patrick has the most important job: monitoring the Big Dig’s technologically pioneering infrastructure to make sure it’s holding up now that drivers are using it every day, particularly since the NTSB report indicates a lack of attention to long-term performance in at least one “safety-critical” area, the fallen ceiling. A key question is whether the tunnels will hold up over time better than have the assets that so many states built so shabbily in the middle of the last century, such as the old Artery and the Tappan Zee Bridge that connects New York City to upstate. The Brooklyn Bridge has lasted, seemingly, forever: Will the Big Dig?
The wrong lesson to take from the Big Dig is that other states shouldn’t bother with ambitious infrastructure. While the Big Dig’s real worth will be measured in decades, its impact so far, three years after workers dismantled the Central Artery, shows its value. Travel time through downtown at afternoon rush hour is down from nearly 20 minutes to less than three, consistent with pre-construction estimates. Elsewhere on the underground highways, travel times are between one-quarter and two-thirds shorter; average speeds in some sections have shot from ten miles per hour to 43 (speed, rather than drivers’ veering toward too many exits in slow traffic, is the tunnels’ biggest safety problem). Airport trips are between one-half and three-quarters shorter. A 62 percent drop in hours spent on the new roads saves nearly $200 million annually in time and fuel.
For the first time in generations, downtown Boston viewed from above is unchoked by traffic. Cars zoom beneath the ground and reappear, emerging to leave the city over the Zakim Bridge. Downtown’s biggest challenge is making sure that the still-unfinished “greenway” parks, where the Artery used to be, weave Boston, its waterfront, and its neighborhoods together again.
Investors and residents are responding positively to the infrastructure improvement. As the Boston Globe reported in 2004, commercial properties along the old Artery increased in value by 79 percent in 15 years, nearly double the citywide increase of 41 percent. Owners have reconfigured buildings to open views where they once bricked up windows, and are renovating property in other newly accessible parts of Boston. The North End’s Italian restaurants are putting sidewalk cafés where they once hid from the Artery. The North End won’t be the North End of 1950, though, just because the Artery is gone. “The Artery preserved us,” says Fredda Hollander, a longtime resident. Tourists and well-heeled potential residents once put off by the physical and psychological barrier now happily wander over from other parts of the city, pushing up both commercial and residential prices.
By taking so long, Massachusetts has proven that infrastructure investments are for future generations. To longtime Bostonians, the new parkland may always be a marker of a phantom Artery, and the Big Dig may always be a scandal. But Boston is welcoming residents and visitors who know nothing about the Artery or the saga surrounding its successor. The state’s and city’s job is to make sure that the Big Dig runs smoothly in the future so that their new constituents don’t have to learn about it.
Nicole Gelinas, a City Journal contributing editor and the Searle Freedom Trust Fellow at the Manhattan Institute, is a Chartered Financial Analyst.
Nicole Gelinas, City Journal (article)
America’s most ambitious infrastructure project inspired engineering marvels—and colossal mismanagement.
States, cities, and towns across America must spend hundreds of billions of dollars annually to preserve the nation’s infrastructure—the backbone of its private-sector economy—and yet more to build the next generation of roads, bridges, tunnels, and dams. Spending so much money wisely is daunting. The good news: no matter how complex and expensive any future project is, it’s unlikely to be more so than the Big Dig, Massachusetts’s three-decade-long quest to bury and expand the Central Artery, Boston’s major interstate highway, and carve out a new underwater tunnel to Logan Airport.
Conceived in the 1970s and finished, more or less, in 2005, the Big Dig is modern America’s most ambitious urban-infrastructure project, spanning six presidents and seven governors, costing $14.8 billion, and featuring many never-before-done engineering and construction marvels. Long before construction peaked around the turn of the millennium, eating up $100 million a month for three years, the Big Dig was a local legend, spawning dozens of jokes. (Wouldn’t it be cheaper to raise Boston than to bury the highway? Congressman Barney Frank asked.) Later, when fewer people viewed the Dig whimsically, it was the setting of a 2002 murder-mystery novel. And last year, after falling concrete panels in a Big Dig tunnel that had been open for three years killed a 38-year-old car passenger, the project became a reminder that infrastructure failure can exact a cruel price.
Every major decision that could conceivably be made on an infrastructure project was made on the Big Dig, from how to pay for it to how to forge the public and political support for it to how to manage its construction and maintenance. Its stewards have encountered every imaginable public-infrastructure pitfall, and fallen into many. The Big Dig’s story is an invaluable lesson: How can America invest in infrastructure—and do it smart?
The reasons for the Big Dig date back nearly 80 years. In 1930, a city planning board noted that Boston’s “street system should be adapted to the requirements of the motor age” and proposed an elevated expressway. The Central Artery’s first planners acknowledged that “the erection of . . . elevated structures . . . in downtown Boston” would hurt some residents’ quality of life. But a “vehicular subway”—the first mention of the idea that, half a century later, would become the Big Dig—“would interfere with sewers and with . . . rapid transit subways.” The state and city had the luxury of deciding to build an elevated highway because bottom-up, Jane Jacobs–inspired urban coalitions didn’t exist yet to thwart the era’s top-down, Robert Moses–style urban planners.
The Great Depression and the Second World War temporarily interfered with the idea. By the late 1940s, Boston still didn’t have its highway, despite two decades of planning—and despite the increasing need for fast access to the city, which was hemorrhaging jobs to the suburbs. But in 1949, six years before Congress and President Eisenhower funded the Interstate Highway System, Massachusetts started building the hideous green steel Central Artery that would scar Boston, physically and psychologically, for the rest of the century. “Boston was a pioneer, but this was bad pioneering,” says Rick Dimino, former city transportation commissioner and today president of the business group A Better City.
It’s easy to follow officials’ reasoning for building the Artery along Boston’s waterfront. That’s where Boston’s business district, once centered on shipping, was located, after all. But the Artery vivisected Boston. It barred pedestrians from the water. It overwhelmed low-rise streets, a historic outdoor fruit and vegetable market, and even the historic Faneuil Hall with traffic, noise, and shadow. It erased swaths of the working-class Italian North End, displacing 573 businesses—mostly small shops and trading firms—and hundreds of families. Owners of some buildings that escaped the bulldozers bricked over windows that faced the Artery. Boston understood the Artery’s impact so quickly that in 1954 it changed tack and buried a last stretch in a tunnel.
Though it did enable suburban workers to get to new office jobs, the Artery quickly became obsolete. Its intended daily capacity was 70,000 cars, but it soon groaned under 170,000. Poorly designed and constructed, it had structural problems and an accident rate four times the national average, because drivers veering toward the Artery’s abundance of downtown exits collided with drivers continuing to the increasingly busy Logan Airport. The building of the Artery turned Bostonians so vehemently against highways that the state halted their construction in the early seventies, killing a planned inner belt that, after displacing another 4,000 families, would have carried traffic from the downtown Artery to other parts of the city. But because the belt and the Artery had been conceived as an integrated system, Artery traffic had nowhere to go. Little more than a decade after the Artery opened, Massachusetts and Boston started scheming to junk it.
When Governor Michael Dukakis’s administration started thinking about fixing this mess in the seventies and early eighties, it had learned the lessons of the Artery’s construction well. But how to fix the Artery, and heal the downtown neighborhoods that it sliced through, without uprooting more residents and slapping a “closed for construction” sign on Boston? How to ease traffic by building an airport tunnel that, unlike the two existing tunnels, would bypass downtown, when the politically powerful neighborhood near the airport opposed new traffic and the seizing of homes?
If Robert Moses and Jane Jacobs had a child, it might have been Fred Salvucci, Dukakis’s transportation secretary, who concocted the Big Dig project. Armed with two MIT engineering degrees, Salvucci had fought the inner belt from city hall before joining Dukakis; he even had firsthand experience of how highway construction affects cities, having seen the state seize and raze his elderly grandmother’s house to make way for a road. Salvucci remembers persuading Dukakis to support the Big Dig by making two crucial pledges: “It would enhance the urban environment rather than degrade it, and there would be no taking of housing.” The state then won the public over by mollifying anyone, anywhere, who had anything at all to do with the project. “We learned from Westway,” says Salvucci, referring to New York’s plan to depress its West Side Highway, which failed because the city didn’t garner various interest groups’ support before seeking congressional approval.
Massachusetts’s task was partly northeastern politics as usual. Unions knew that they’d benefit from a “project labor agreement,” through which their workers would agree not to strike if contractors, even nonunion ones, would hire through union halls. Police officers would get tens of millions of dollars annually in overtime, since local law mandates that a policeman watch over any work site. Minority-group reps were pleased with a pledge to hire blacks and women for construction jobs.
But the state had a new task, one that would become a feature of big infrastructure projects nationwide: “mitigation.” Broadly speaking, mitigation was the state’s promise to alleviate the Big Dig’s impact on Boston, from interrupting business to harming the environment. Mitigation eventually accounted for about one-third of the Big Dig’s cost—from the thousands of dollars needed to outfit North End apartments with air conditioning, soundproof windows, and firm mattresses as residents settled in for a decade of construction to the more than $1 billion needed to rework a planned bridge that business leaders, residents, and the nearby city of Cambridge considered ugly.
Mitigation made downtown businesses happy, promising not to shut down any of the Central Artery’s six lanes during construction, and promising further that companies such as Fidelity Investments wouldn’t lack electricity or telephones for even a few hours as contractors dug up miles of utilities to make room for underground highways. Mitigation made Gillette, Boston’s biggest manufacturer, happy, working with the company to marry its complicated underwater infrastructure to the Big Dig’s. Mitigation made the post office happy, building temporary roads to a distribution station. Mitigation made airport neighbors happy, vowing that cars from the airport tunnel wouldn’t exit onto residential land. Mitigation also made environmentalists happy with its promise to preserve as open space three-quarters of the land that the Artery’s demolition would create (the highway tunnels that would run underneath couldn’t support heavy construction, anyway). It made more ambitious environmentalists happy, promising to improve mass transit and to use some of the excavated dirt—which, because it had saltwater in it, couldn’t be dumped inland—to transform a Boston Harbor island from a noxious landfill into a beachfront park. It made archaeologists happy, paying to catalog artifacts dating back to colonial days. It didn’t make rats happy: after near-hysteria that construction would unleash vermin whose underground lairs also dated to colonial days, the project launched an aggressive rodent-control program.
The mitigation, some of which was sensible, tempered even reasonable criticism of the Big Dig. Few locals voiced skepticism during planning. Once you got your own interest protected, you kept quiet, to make sure that the project, free of local opposition, would win federal funding. Thanks largely to mitigation efforts, more than 80 percent of Boston residents and nearly two-thirds of state residents supported the Big Dig in its early years.
Mitigation notwithstanding, the Big Dig still would probably be a near-forgotten dream like Westway if not for Massachusetts’s Washington dominance in the late seventies and eighties. Democrats ran Capitol Hill, and Massachusetts’s wholly Democratic congressional delegation had a lot of seniority. Everyone in Massachusetts thus assumed that they would fund the project with “ten-cent dollars,” of which the feds would pay the other 90.
Even so, Massachusetts got its initial federal funding only because of Salvucci’s and Dukakis’s brilliant and successful argument: since it had built its Artery before the Interstate Highway System paid for such projects, the state should be able to use the federal money that it hadn’t spent back then to rebuild the Artery. This fluke explains why Massachusetts, at a time when other northeastern states were ignoring infrastructure in favor of expanding social programs like Med-icaid, focused on nuts and bolts: it knew that if it did so, it could tap into “free” federal money. Taking this argument to Washington, legendary Massachusetts Democrat Tip O’Neill, the House’s majority leader and soon to be its Speaker, in 1976 inserted “placeholder” funds for the Big Dig into a congressional blueprint of costs to complete the Interstate Highway System.
A decade later, though, President Reagan didn’t care to give Massachusetts Democrats billions for what skeptics considered a “highway beautification project.” When Reagan vetoed a 1987 highway bill that contained the Big Dig’s first significant federal funding, the real politics started. Tip, and Ted Kennedy in the Senate, garnered enough supporters, including 13 Republicans, for an override. In a preview of how Washington would work over the next two decades, they approved goodies that other states wanted, too. Wavering out-of-state politicians came on board.
After Tip’s override, local Big Dig planners never worried about pesky things like whether cost estimates and project scope were reasonable. Massachusetts had proved that it was more powerful than the president; surely there would always be more money where its initial funding came from. But over the ensuing decades, the Big Dig’s price tag waxed and Massachusetts’s congressional power waned. Washington imposed a firm dollar cap on its Big Dig spending at the turn of the millennium, leaving Massachusetts to pay the rest. State taxpayers would eventually foot nearly half the project’s cost.
The Bay State’s experience is a lesson for state officials: the clout you have today may be gone tomorrow. If you think that an ambitious project’s benefits exceed its costs, convince your taxpayers up front—rather than getting Washington, which may change its mind down the road, to get its taxpayers to pay.
In retrospect, it’s amazing how much went right after construction started in 1991. Over 14 years, Massachusetts, its consultants, and its contractors carved canyons under Boston while the city hummed above. They designed and built seven and a half miles of highway—161 miles of separate lanes—more than half of them in tunnels. They built six interchanges and 200 bridges.
One of the innovations that made this work possible was the slurry wall, also used at New York’s World Trade Center, which allowed the state, as Salvucci puts it, to build huge underground tunnels “arthroscopically,” without pockmarking Boston with huge uncovered holes. The slurry wall, in effect, let Boston dig itself up without shutting itself down. The Big Dig’s general reliance on new technology was a major factor in one of the project officials’ biggest decisions: choosing a consortium made up of Bechtel and Parsons Brinckerhoff as the “management consultant.” Parsons was an expert in innovative urban tunneling dating to the early twentieth century, when it built New York City’s subways. Bechtel had constructed the Hoover Dam as well as most of modern Saudi Arabia, and had fabled political connections to accompany its engineering and logistics mystique. Caspar Weinberger and George Shultz, both in Reagan’s cabinet, were Bechtel men—though that connection hadn’t helped Salvucci at veto time.
One of the creative, audacious, and potentially disastrous things that Bechtel and Parsons, as well as the state’s contractors, did right on the Big Dig was jacking up the Central Artery—replacing the half-million-ton highway’s 69 support columns with temporary “underpinnings” so that contractors could remove the columns and make way for the tunnels. “Pinning the Artery” wasn’t the Big Dig’s only never-before-done feat. The striking Zakim Bridge—the one redesigned after community outrage—is the world’s widest cable-stayed asymmetrical bridge, expanding from eight lanes to ten to account for complicated traffic flow.
Elsewhere, underneath active railroad tracks, engineers froze ground too soft to withstand construction and pushed prebuilt tunnel sections through. They erected a huge temporary dam to dry out a basin in which to construct tunnel segments—and then flooded the basin, floating the segments and resinking them in their new underwater homes. They built underground bridges to hold up subways, threading highway tunnels above and below mass transit. And though insurance tables had predicted 40 serious accidents during the project, the Big Dig suffered only a quarter of that total, and three construction deaths—showing how much things had changed since, say, the 1870s, when raising the Brooklyn Bridge took 27 lives.
Leave it to Massachusetts, though, to turn the Big Dig’s reputation from resounding success to humiliating failure—first in terms of the project’s cost. From day one—even after accounting for politicians’ erring on the low side to gain public approval—the Big Dig was fated to cost more than its 1982 price tag of $2.6 billion.
That number didn’t include much of the project’s mitigation, including big changes like the billion-plus extra to remake the Zakim Bridge. Nor did it include the real costs of staying on schedule. The Big Dig often let its contractors start work on pieces of the project before designs for other key parts were complete. This approach—part of the project’s philosophy of getting things done now and asking questions later—meant expensive changes to contracts. By the early 1990s, as the state added new work, and as its consultants and contractors looked underground to see what was actually there, the Big Dig’s price tag had ballooned to nearly $8 billion.
True, critics aren’t being entirely fair when they compare the project’s final cost, $14.8 billion, with the initial estimate; $2.6 billion in 1982 is $5.6 billion today, thanks to inflation. And inflation has similarly distorted the cost of the many expensive changes made to the project—because the more realistic cost estimates that accounted for those changes were also calculated in then-current dollars, rather than in the dollars that the state eventually had to pay. Still, there’s a lesson here for managers of other infrastructure projects: be careful with that first number, because it can become a permanent benchmark against which to measure success or failure.
Perhaps it’s understandable that inflation and massive increases in scope would swell the project’s price tag. But the Big Dig’s planners truly failed the public through a deliberate decision: for years, they used dubious accounting methods that hid true costs.
In 1994, two years into construction, Bechtel and Parsons officials compiled convincing evidence that the Big Dig would cost nearly $14 billion in completion-year dollars—far more than public officials were disclosing—and took their findings to the state, says former state inspector general Bob Cerasoli, who supervised a 2001 report on the Big Dig’s finances. But the state didn’t tell the public, so alarming Bechtel that its president flew to Boston to see then-governor William Weld. Afterward, according to Cerasoli’s report, “state managers directed state and [Bechtel and Parsons] staff to . . . maintain the fiction of an . . . $8 billion project. . . . They did so by applying a largely semantic series of exclusions, deductions, and accounting assumptions that covered up the $6 billion difference,” often with the knowledge of federal highway officials.
Some state officials thought that if they delayed disclosing money woes, the public would be so thrilled with early improvements like the Ted Williams Tunnel, which opened in 1995, that they wouldn’t pay attention to boring finances. But as an internal “pros and cons” document noted, if the state didn’t inform bondholders, it risked fraud charges—and, in fact, federal securities regulators later reprimanded Weld’s Big Dig boss, James Kerasiotes, for “misleading” investors. Even more pressing, the state needed actual money to continue its project, so it had to come clean despite worries that “we could become the central controversy of the next year in Massachusetts.” It was after the state finally fessed up that the feds imposed their permanent funding cap on the project.
Massachusetts’s desire to insulate the public from the Big Dig’s costs also led to a fateful decision by Governor Weld. Weld needed a ready source of money for the project, without hiking taxes or cutting spending elsewhere. So he transferred the Big Dig’s assets to the Massachusetts Turnpike Authority, an unaccountable public entity akin to New York’s Metropolitan Transportation Authority, in return for some of the authority’s future toll revenue, which would back Big Dig bonds. This costly trade added a new layer of bureaucracy to the project, which needed, more than anything, one elected person to be ultimately accountable. After last year’s fatal ceiling collapse, Mitt Romney, governor for nearly four years, could point to the fact that his predecessor’s appointee still ran the Big Dig.
But the Big Dig’s biggest pitfall was that Massachusetts never understood a basic fact: that it couldn’t pay someone else to assume its own responsibility for an immensely complex, risky project. As the National Transportation Safety Board (NTSB) would later say in its report on the 2006 ceiling collapse, Bechtel and Parsons, the state’s long-term consultants, were “performing the role that would normally be carried out by a government agency, specifically, the state highway department.”
Since costs turned the Big Dig into a scandal, the public has often seen Bechtel and Parsons as its villains. The perception in Massachusetts—never dispelled by state officials—is that the duo’s thousand-plus white-collar workers, dwarfing their few dozen public-sector counterparts, ran the Big Dig, expertly controlling and manipulating designers, contractors, and information, without letting anyone else have much say, from colleagues at lowly engineering firms to meddling public officials. But even assuming the worst—and the reality is more complicated—people usually can’t manipulate you unless you let them. As early as 1991, the state’s inspector general warned of the “increasingly apparent vulnerabilities . . . of [Massachusetts’s] long-term dependence on a consultant” whose contract had an “open-ended structure” and “inadequate monitoring.” The main deficiency, as later IG reports detailed, was that Bechtel and Parsons—as “preliminary designer,” “design coordinator,” “construction coordinator,” and “contract administrator”—were often in charge of checking their own work. If, say, the team noticed in managing construction that a contract was over budget because of problems rooted in preliminary design, it didn’t have much incentive to speak up.
The state should also have known that when consultancy work will last years and when consultants plan to introduce technologies so sophisticated that they can overwhelm the state’s ability to oversee them, the state’s going to wind up in a vulnerable position. Massachusetts would have been smart to introduce some checks and balances early on—perhaps splitting the work that Bechtel and Parsons were doing into smaller parts, having separate consultants for preliminary design and for “project management” work, or keeping some of the “management” in house. Instead, in the name of cost efficiencies, the state further blurred the distinction between public and private sectors by folding Bechtel and Parsons employees and its own workers into one “integrated project organization” in 1998. And though the state’s Massachusetts Turnpike Authority was at the top of the new organization chart—which was immensely complicated by multiple layers of theoretical oversight, including supervision from federal highway officials as well as the feds’ General Accounting Office—the state designated Bechtel and Parsons its “owner’s representative” in some areas, complicating even further the answer to the straightforward question: Who was in charge?
Massachusetts’s laissez-faire attitude followed from a fundamental misapprehension: that Bechtel and Parsons were their partners, not outside consultants, and were thus assuming some performance risk. In a 1994 interview, Kerasiotes, then the state’s transportation secretary, argued that Bechtel’s incentive to perform its job properly was its reputation: “Go to San Francisco, walk in the lobby” of Bechtel’s headquarters, he suggested. “What you’re going to see [are] prominent pictures of the Central Artery. . . . If they are causing this project to screw up, . . . they’re not going to market themselves that way.”
But Bechtel and Parsons never took on any performance risk—risk that the public sector carries as the ultimate funder and manager. If the project were an investment-banking deal, Bechtel would have been an advisor counseling a company on whether to undertake a merger, not an investor in that merger. “Our contractual responsibility as management consultant was to deliver a professional standard of care, not to guarantee the contractors’ work,” says Keith Sibley, Bechtel and Parsons’s longtime Big Dig director. It’s a crucial distinction: Bechtel and Parsons promised not perfect results but professional advisory and management work—and reasonable people may differ about what constitutes “professional.” It’s particularly difficult to assess decisions made under an “integrated project organization,” where everything is opaque about who was responsible for which decisions, or whether particular decisions were the result of public and private collaboration.
This problem of murky responsibility came up repeatedly during the Big Dig, but most tragically with the ceiling collapse. Designers engineered a lightweight ceiling for the tunnel in which Milena del Valle died. But Massachusetts, annoyed by cost overruns and cleanliness problems on a similar ceiling, and at the suggestion of federal highway officials, decided to fit the new tunnel with a cheaper ceiling, which turned out to be heavier. Realizing that hanging concrete where no built-in anchors existed to hold it would be a difficult job, the ceiling’s designer, a company called Gannett Fleming, called for contractors to install the ceiling with an unusually large built-in margin for extra weight. Shortly after contractors installed the ceiling—using anchors held by a high-strength epoxy, as Gannett specified—workers noticed that it was coming loose. Consultants and contractors decided to take it apart and reinstall it. Two years later, after a contractor told Bechtel that “several anchors appear to be pulling away from the concrete,” Bechtel directed it to “set new anchors and retest.” After the resetting and retesting, the tunnel opened to traffic, with fatal consequences.
In hindsight, they all did the wrong thing. The real problem was that the poorly labeled and poorly marketed “fast set” epoxy that the contractors used for the ceiling wasn’t suitable for long-term loads of any type: the company that made the glue, Powers Fasteners, didn’t warn clearly that the epoxy wasn’t interchangeable with another, suitable “standard set” epoxy that it made. The National Transportation Safety Board’s report noted the company’s failure, and Massachusetts has indicted Powers for criminal negligence. But the feds also mentioned that neither Gannett nor Bechtel and Parsons had thought about the ceiling’s long-term performance, when the earlier ceiling failures should have made it clear to both Bechtel and a construction contractor that reinstallation hadn’t worked. Finally, the report points out, once the tunnel opened in 2003, Massachusetts was supposed to conduct regular inspections, which likely would have revealed the ceiling panels’ obvious displacement well before the collapse.
Massachusetts, after taking a hands-off approach to its project’s risks during construction, is today using its most fearsome power—the power to indict—to push Bechtel and Parsons to settle with the state for hundreds of millions of dollars and avoid criminal charges. Massachusetts’s approach is a warning to future private-sector contractors and consultants: if something goes disastrously wrong with a project in which thousands of critical decisions were made with public and private cooperation, the state may use the criminal-justice system as a cudgel to deflect its own accountability.
Massachusetts might have avoided some problems by transferring certain Big Dig risks to the private sector through discrete, well-defined deals: signing a long-term contract with a firm to help build, operate, and maintain the Zakim Bridge, for instance. Such an endeavor, though, would have required aggressive public-sector management of initial costs, scope, and complex contract language—things the state hasn’t excelled at.
Any risk transfer, moreover, would have been limited. Massachusetts could never have turned over full technical, operational, and financial risks of the Big Dig to any reputable company or group. The project had too many unknowns. Smart, reputable companies don’t take unlimited risks at the behest of a fickle, indecisive client for a limited profit. The best thing Massachusetts could have done was to realize the project’s real risks so that it could manage them effectively.
Now Democratic governor Deval Patrick has the most important job: monitoring the Big Dig’s technologically pioneering infrastructure to make sure it’s holding up now that drivers are using it every day, particularly since the NTSB report indicates a lack of attention to long-term performance in at least one “safety-critical” area, the fallen ceiling. A key question is whether the tunnels will hold up over time better than have the assets that so many states built so shabbily in the middle of the last century, such as the old Artery and the Tappan Zee Bridge that connects New York City to upstate. The Brooklyn Bridge has lasted, seemingly, forever: Will the Big Dig?
The wrong lesson to take from the Big Dig is that other states shouldn’t bother with ambitious infrastructure. While the Big Dig’s real worth will be measured in decades, its impact so far, three years after workers dismantled the Central Artery, shows its value. Travel time through downtown at afternoon rush hour is down from nearly 20 minutes to less than three, consistent with pre-construction estimates. Elsewhere on the underground highways, travel times are between one-quarter and two-thirds shorter; average speeds in some sections have shot from ten miles per hour to 43 (speed, rather than drivers’ veering toward too many exits in slow traffic, is the tunnels’ biggest safety problem). Airport trips are between one-half and three-quarters shorter. A 62 percent drop in hours spent on the new roads saves nearly $200 million annually in time and fuel.
For the first time in generations, downtown Boston viewed from above is unchoked by traffic. Cars zoom beneath the ground and reappear, emerging to leave the city over the Zakim Bridge. Downtown’s biggest challenge is making sure that the still-unfinished “greenway” parks, where the Artery used to be, weave Boston, its waterfront, and its neighborhoods together again.
Investors and residents are responding positively to the infrastructure improvement. As the Boston Globe reported in 2004, commercial properties along the old Artery increased in value by 79 percent in 15 years, nearly double the citywide increase of 41 percent. Owners have reconfigured buildings to open views where they once bricked up windows, and are renovating property in other newly accessible parts of Boston. The North End’s Italian restaurants are putting sidewalk cafés where they once hid from the Artery. The North End won’t be the North End of 1950, though, just because the Artery is gone. “The Artery preserved us,” says Fredda Hollander, a longtime resident. Tourists and well-heeled potential residents once put off by the physical and psychological barrier now happily wander over from other parts of the city, pushing up both commercial and residential prices.
By taking so long, Massachusetts has proven that infrastructure investments are for future generations. To longtime Bostonians, the new parkland may always be a marker of a phantom Artery, and the Big Dig may always be a scandal. But Boston is welcoming residents and visitors who know nothing about the Artery or the saga surrounding its successor. The state’s and city’s job is to make sure that the Big Dig runs smoothly in the future so that their new constituents don’t have to learn about it.
Nicole Gelinas, a City Journal contributing editor and the Searle Freedom Trust Fellow at the Manhattan Institute, is a Chartered Financial Analyst.
November 27, 2007 Editorial: Tysons Corner exodus is an early warning sign
Editorial: Tysons Corner exodus is an early warning sign
Nov 27, 2007 by The Washington DC Examiner Newspaper (article)
WASHINGTON (Map, News) - In an act of astonishing presumption, utility relocation has already begun on the Dulles Rail project, as The Examiner’s Bill Flook reported last week, even though the project has not yet gotten final approval from the Federal Transit Administration. The fact that the FTA is still scrutinizing the price tag of this misbegotten project doesn’t seem to faze the Metropolitan Washington Airports Authority, which is now managing it.
It should. Dulles Corridor Users Group president Chris Walker reminded FTA officials in a letter he sent them this week that the proposed Silver Line is “deficient in all respects to the San Jose [Bay Area Rapid Transit] proposal, which the FTA has already turned down” for federal funding.
There are also early warning signs that this too-expensive Metrorail project will do more harm than good in Northern Virginia, literally killing Virginia’s golden goose.
Instead of early birds flocking to Tysons Corner to take advantage of Dulles Rail’s many supposed benefits, businesses have actually begun bailing out. More corporate tenants have left Tysons than leased office space there this year. This unexpected exodus is most likely being driven by the anticipation of five years or more of major construction chaos and tolls of up to $5 per trip to pay for it. But there is another, more ominous explanation.
McLean Citizens Association Board member Mark Zetts says Tysons Corner will never become a successful transit-oriented development center like Arlington’s Rosslyn-Ballston corridor because Tysons is sealed off by already overcrowded interstates, while the R-B area has 40 access lanes — one every quarter of a mile — that facilitate the smooth flow of traffic.
Fairfax County still does not have a land use plan reflecting the unaddressed problem of poor access, which will be compounded — not alleviated — by a transit project that eats up valuable right of way on Route 7, the main arterial serving Tysons Corner. With no money left to upgrade key interchanges that connect the surrounding interstates to Tysons roads, the resulting traffic congestion will be much worse after Dulles Rail is built.
Local motorists and businesses are expected to pay $1 million per day for a transit project that will make their lives much more expensive and far less convenient.
Who wants to stick around for that?
Nov 27, 2007 by The Washington DC Examiner Newspaper (article)
WASHINGTON (Map, News) - In an act of astonishing presumption, utility relocation has already begun on the Dulles Rail project, as The Examiner’s Bill Flook reported last week, even though the project has not yet gotten final approval from the Federal Transit Administration. The fact that the FTA is still scrutinizing the price tag of this misbegotten project doesn’t seem to faze the Metropolitan Washington Airports Authority, which is now managing it.
It should. Dulles Corridor Users Group president Chris Walker reminded FTA officials in a letter he sent them this week that the proposed Silver Line is “deficient in all respects to the San Jose [Bay Area Rapid Transit] proposal, which the FTA has already turned down” for federal funding.
There are also early warning signs that this too-expensive Metrorail project will do more harm than good in Northern Virginia, literally killing Virginia’s golden goose.
Instead of early birds flocking to Tysons Corner to take advantage of Dulles Rail’s many supposed benefits, businesses have actually begun bailing out. More corporate tenants have left Tysons than leased office space there this year. This unexpected exodus is most likely being driven by the anticipation of five years or more of major construction chaos and tolls of up to $5 per trip to pay for it. But there is another, more ominous explanation.
McLean Citizens Association Board member Mark Zetts says Tysons Corner will never become a successful transit-oriented development center like Arlington’s Rosslyn-Ballston corridor because Tysons is sealed off by already overcrowded interstates, while the R-B area has 40 access lanes — one every quarter of a mile — that facilitate the smooth flow of traffic.
Fairfax County still does not have a land use plan reflecting the unaddressed problem of poor access, which will be compounded — not alleviated — by a transit project that eats up valuable right of way on Route 7, the main arterial serving Tysons Corner. With no money left to upgrade key interchanges that connect the surrounding interstates to Tysons roads, the resulting traffic congestion will be much worse after Dulles Rail is built.
Local motorists and businesses are expected to pay $1 million per day for a transit project that will make their lives much more expensive and far less convenient.
Who wants to stick around for that?
Labels:
Dulles Rail Project,
Tysons Corner,
Tysonstunnel.org
November 28, 2007 (Tysons Corner) Tunnel supporters sue to halt rail line
Tunnel supporters sue to halt rail line
Nov 28, 2007 by William C. Flook, The Examiner (article)
WASHINGTON (Map, News) - Tysonstunnel.org, a group that has sought for more than a year to persuade officials to run the planned Dulles rail line underneath Tysons Corner, filed a lawsuit against the U.S. Department of Transportation on Tuesday aiming to halt the entire project until its plan is reconsidered.
The group was unexpectedly joined in the suit by Tysons firm Ratner Cos., which operates Hair Cuttery and Bubbles Salons. They are represented by Gary Baise, a Republican lawyer who ran an unsuccessful bid to unseat Fairfax County Chairman Gerry Connolly this year.
The suit signals that Tysonstunnel has largely abandoned any hope to pursuade Virginia Gov. Tim Kaine to reverse course on the planned overhead track through Tysons.
Kaine officially abandoned the tunnel proposal in September 2006 after being warned by the Federal Transit Administration that the popular route would cost hundreds of millions of dollars more than the alternative and make the project ineligible for federal funding.
Tysonstunnel.org also is seeking to put the project out to competitive bidding, which it argues never occurred under the project’s public-private partnership. The lawsuit says the FTA cannot approve the rail project because it does not follow its guidelines for “full and open competition.”
“We don’t want it stopped, we want it corrected so we can move forward,” Tysonstunnel president Scott Monett said. “That’s what we have been saying from the beginning. ... What we’re asking them to do is follow their own rules that if a project is to receive federal funds that it be competitively bid.”
FTA spokesman Wes Irvin could not be reached for comment Tuesday. A spokeswoman for the project declined to comment.
The Dulles rail procurement process has been a point of contention since the inception of the project. Officials are building the rail through Virginia’s Public-Private Transportation Act, which allowed for closed-door negotiation on price and details, instead of the state’s standard procurement law.
A group made up by Bechtel Infrastructure and Washington Group International won a contract earlier this year to design and build the rail’s first 11.6-mile phase. That initial leg is projected to cost $2.5 billion, if $300 million in cuts are accepted by the FTA.
wflook@dcexaminer.com
Nov 28, 2007 by William C. Flook, The Examiner (article)
WASHINGTON (Map, News) - Tysonstunnel.org, a group that has sought for more than a year to persuade officials to run the planned Dulles rail line underneath Tysons Corner, filed a lawsuit against the U.S. Department of Transportation on Tuesday aiming to halt the entire project until its plan is reconsidered.
The group was unexpectedly joined in the suit by Tysons firm Ratner Cos., which operates Hair Cuttery and Bubbles Salons. They are represented by Gary Baise, a Republican lawyer who ran an unsuccessful bid to unseat Fairfax County Chairman Gerry Connolly this year.
The suit signals that Tysonstunnel has largely abandoned any hope to pursuade Virginia Gov. Tim Kaine to reverse course on the planned overhead track through Tysons.
Kaine officially abandoned the tunnel proposal in September 2006 after being warned by the Federal Transit Administration that the popular route would cost hundreds of millions of dollars more than the alternative and make the project ineligible for federal funding.
Tysonstunnel.org also is seeking to put the project out to competitive bidding, which it argues never occurred under the project’s public-private partnership. The lawsuit says the FTA cannot approve the rail project because it does not follow its guidelines for “full and open competition.”
“We don’t want it stopped, we want it corrected so we can move forward,” Tysonstunnel president Scott Monett said. “That’s what we have been saying from the beginning. ... What we’re asking them to do is follow their own rules that if a project is to receive federal funds that it be competitively bid.”
FTA spokesman Wes Irvin could not be reached for comment Tuesday. A spokeswoman for the project declined to comment.
The Dulles rail procurement process has been a point of contention since the inception of the project. Officials are building the rail through Virginia’s Public-Private Transportation Act, which allowed for closed-door negotiation on price and details, instead of the state’s standard procurement law.
A group made up by Bechtel Infrastructure and Washington Group International won a contract earlier this year to design and build the rail’s first 11.6-mile phase. That initial leg is projected to cost $2.5 billion, if $300 million in cuts are accepted by the FTA.
wflook@dcexaminer.com
Tuesday, November 27, 2007
How Safe is America's Roadway System?
Published by the FHWA.
Road Safety Fact Sheet
Safety: A FHWA Vital Few - Fact Sheet
How Safe is America's Roadway System?
The U.S. roadway system's positive trends have plateaued at a fatality rate that is the lowest in history at 1.5 deaths per 100 million miles of travel (down from 5.5 fatalities in 1966). However, that's still not good enough. In 2003, almost 3 million people were injured and 42,643 people died on our nation's roads. The number of annual roadway fatalities had remained virtually unchanged (40,000-42,000) for the past ten years, but now there is an upward trend.
How Significant is the Roadway Safety Problem?
Roadway safety is a serious, national public health issue. In 2003, there were 42,643 fatalities and almost 3 million injuries occurred on our nation's roads.
Out of the total 42,643 fatalities in 2003, there were:
25,321 road departure fatalities (59%)
9,213 intersection fatalities (21%)
4,749 pedestrian fatalities (11%)
Can You Put This In Perspective?
Fatalities
One road departure fatality every 21 minutes
One intersection fatality every hour
One pedestrian fatality about every two hours
Average Day
117 fatalities a day
30% of daily fatalities (35) are under the age of 25
Daily financial loss is $630 million
What is the FHWA Goal to Reduce Roadway Fatalities?
As a safety agency dedicated to saving lives, FHWA has identified improving roadway safety and mobility as a Vital Few -- one FHWA's top three priorities. The other two Vital Few priorities are Congestion and Environmental Streamlining.
The FHWA Safety Programs focuses on high risk areas, such as road departure, intersections and pedestrian safety, in order to make the biggest difference in improving traffic safety.
To reduce road departure, intersection and pedestrian fatalities by 10% by 2007,
FHWA is focusing on six national target areas, two of which are concerned with road departure. They are as follows:
- Road Departure Fatalities: Reduce run-off-the-road, head-on and opposite direction side-swipe crashes by 10% by 2007. Save 2,514 lives.
- Preventing road departure fatalities from occurring
- Minimizing the severity of road departure crashes
- Intersection Fatalities: Reduce by 10% by 2007. Save 921 lives.
- Pedestrian Fatalities: Reduce by 10% by 2007. Save 475 lives.
- Safety Belt Use: Raise seat belt use to 90% by 2008. Save 5,536 lives.
- Safety Awareness: FHWA is working to make sure that safety is an integral part of planning, project development and operations at the state, MPO and local levels.
- What is the FHWA Doing to Solve This National Safety Problem?
FHWA provides national safety leadership through: conducting innovative safety research; setting national highway safety guidelines; and promoting proven or promising safety technologies.
FHWA is actively pursuing improved roadway safety through a multi-faceted approach in the fields of engineering, education, enforcement, and coordination with public safety agencies (police and fire services).
FHWA also partners with a variety of organizations that are interested in improving roadway safety including: the International Association of Chiefs of Police (IACP), the Institute of Transportation Engineers (ITE), the American Association of State Highway and Transportation Officials (AASHTO), State Departments of Transportation, the National Association of County Engineers (NACE), the American Public Works Association (APWA) the Governors Highway Safety Association (GHSA), the Transportation Research Board (TRB), the American Automobile Association (AAA), the Association of Metropolitan Planning Organizations (AMPO), and National Association of Regional Councils (NARC).
Engineering
On the engineering front, FHWA both conducts research and supports private sector research into a variety of innovative design features that create safer roads, intersections and pedestrian crossings.
Road safety design features that help to reduce road departures and minimize the severity of roadway crashes include: rumble strips, retroreflective signs, and forgiving roadside hardware (i.e. guardrails and breakaway poles), skid resistance pavements, and all-weather pavement markings.
Intersection safety design features that make intersections safer for drivers and pedestrians include: traffic signal timing, improved signage, exclusive turn lanes, and roundabouts.
Pedestrian safety design features that create safer pedestrian crossings for all pedestrians, including those with disabilities include: pedestrian-signal timings and pedestrian signals; improved lighting to enhance visibility; truncated domes for blind pedestrians; and refuge islands on a median.
In addition, FHWA is currently developing the Interactive Highway Safety Design Model (IHSDM) software -- an innovative road safety evaluation software that marshals available safety knowledge into a useful form for highway planners and designers.
FHWA is also actively promoting the use of proven or promising safety technologies that will help improve roadway safety including: rumble strips, retroreflective signs and pavement markings, and roundabouts. As the federal agency responsible for setting national highway safety guidelines, FHWA issued a technical advisory on rumble strips; is working on national guidelines for minimum sign retroreflectivity levels; and published a comprehensive information guide on roundabouts.
Education
FHWA's safety program has a strong educational component. Through a variety of educational tools and workshops, FHWA is dedicated to improving public safety awareness and updating highway engineers and roadway planners on the latest safety research.
To this end, FHWA has funded and sponsored numerous videos, handbooks, websites, multilingual brochures, CDs, manuals, computer modeling software, clearinghouses and training courses. Although these educational materials and courses are too many to detail here, a few are listed below.
For example, FHWA funded and sponsored the Pedestrian Safety Roadshow (PSRS), a four-hour educational workshop that is designed for use by community leaders, concerned citizens, and business leaders. The purpose of PSRS is twofold: to assist communities in developing their own approach to pedestrian safety and to increase awareness of pedestrian safety concerns.
Also, to help roadway planners and engineers apply the latest research and technologies on the needs of older drivers and pedestrians, FHWA published The Older Driver Highway Design Handbook and also offer a one-day workshop.
Enforcement
As part of our comprehensive safety program, FHWA engineers work closely with state highway engineers and law enforcement officials to identify appropriate engineering safety countermeasures for high risk locations and for new roads. Working with state and local law enforcement is one of the ways that FHWA makes sure that roadway safety is always a top priority.
Partnership Activities
FHWA believes that partnerships create synergy and are very important to improving roadway safety. FHWA participates in roadway safety partnerships with state and local officials, concerned citizens, local business leaders, schools and youth organizations. The partnership activities listed below are just a few of the safety partnerships that FHWA participates in. More information on FHWA partnership activities can be found on the FHWA Office of Safety web site.
FHWA's top partnership is working with AASHTO on the AASHTO Strategic Highway Safety Plan (SHSP). The goal is to reduce the annual number of highway deaths by 9,000 by 2008 to a rate of 1.0 (down from the current rate of 1.5). This will accomplished through improved safety in 22 key areas concerning infrastructure, vehicles, drivers, and emergency medical services (EMS). FHWA's role is that of providing national leadership, direction, and the development and demonstration of new safety innovations, technologies, and programs. (For more information.)
The successful National Work-Zone Safety Information Clearinghouse website is a good example of what can be accomplished when FHWA partners with other roadway safety groups. It was created in a partnership by FHWA and the American Road and Transportation Builders Association (ARTBA) and the Texas Transportation Institute (TTI) handles the site's day-to-day operations. The National Utility Contractors Associations (NUCA) and the Institute of Transportation Engineers (ITE) assist ARTBA in marketing and publicizing the clearinghouse.
Started in 1995 by FHWA, Stop Red Light Running (SRLR) is a national initiative to improve intersection safety by reducing the number of red light running incidents. The American Trauma Society became a partner with FHWA in 1998. Over 200 communities, including local law enforcement departments, are currently part of t his nationwide safety program.
In addition, FHWA is a founding member of the Safety Conscious Planning (SCP) Working Group. This group is a national organization dedicated to providing state and metropolitan planners with “best
practices' and opportunities to integrate safety in the planning process. Other partners in the SCP Working Group include: AASHTO, TRB, GHSA, AAA, AMPO, NARC, ITE, and FHWA's DOT sister agencies -- NHTSA, FTA, and FMCSA. For more information on SCP publications and projects there are two web site addresses.
The extensive implementation of yellow-green fluorescent signs around heavily traveled pedestrian crosswalks at school zones, hospitals and airports, is a visible, day-to-day result of successful FHWA and local community partnerships. To improve pedestrian safety through the use of this new pedestrian sign, FHWA partnered with local police departments, schools and hospitals. This new sign has proven to be more visible than the standard, non-fluorescent yellow sign that had been previously used to warn motorists of pedestrian crossings.
Who Is Responsible for Roadway Safety?
Everyone. We all are responsible for driving, walking, and biking safely on our Nation's roads. The engineers and planners have the responsibility to make sure that roads are designed and operating properly -- with safety for all road users in mind. Drivers and pedestrians have the responsibility to always be alert and obey the traffic rules. Passengers should always buckle up and act responsibly. The police and the courts have the responsibility to make sure that the traffic and pedestrian laws are enforced. Public safety agencies have the responsibility of responding to and securing crash locations and enforcing traffic laws. Local communities and county and state governments need to allocate funding for safe roads and increase public awareness about road safety. Everyone should take responsibility for roadway safety.
10 Tips for Driving and Walking Safely
1. It's your responsibility to drive and walk safely so always be alert and attentive to the motorists and pedestrians around you.
2. Never drink and drive. And don't let friends drive drunk.
3. Always buckle up. The life you save could be your own.
4. Obey traffic signals and signs. They are there to keep you and others safe.
5. Make sure you have plenty of time to get to your destination so you don't feel pressured to speed or disobey traffic signals.
6. Don't give into road rage. Your life and the lives of your passengers are more important than angrily reacting to an irresponsible driver.
7. Pedestrians should always wear light-colored or reflective clothing at night to be more visible to drivers.
8. Before you take a left turn at an intersection, make sure it is safe to do so. (More than one-third of all deaths to vehicle occupants occur in side-impact crashes. Most of these occur at intersections.)
9. Obey the speed limits and make sure you drive carefully through intersections and work zones.
10. Don't drive when you are drowsy. If you are drowsy, pull over at a rest area and take a nap before proceeding.
Road Safety Fact Sheet
Safety: A FHWA Vital Few - Fact Sheet
How Safe is America's Roadway System?
The U.S. roadway system's positive trends have plateaued at a fatality rate that is the lowest in history at 1.5 deaths per 100 million miles of travel (down from 5.5 fatalities in 1966). However, that's still not good enough. In 2003, almost 3 million people were injured and 42,643 people died on our nation's roads. The number of annual roadway fatalities had remained virtually unchanged (40,000-42,000) for the past ten years, but now there is an upward trend.
How Significant is the Roadway Safety Problem?
Roadway safety is a serious, national public health issue. In 2003, there were 42,643 fatalities and almost 3 million injuries occurred on our nation's roads.
Out of the total 42,643 fatalities in 2003, there were:
25,321 road departure fatalities (59%)
9,213 intersection fatalities (21%)
4,749 pedestrian fatalities (11%)
Can You Put This In Perspective?
Fatalities
One road departure fatality every 21 minutes
One intersection fatality every hour
One pedestrian fatality about every two hours
Average Day
117 fatalities a day
30% of daily fatalities (35) are under the age of 25
Daily financial loss is $630 million
What is the FHWA Goal to Reduce Roadway Fatalities?
As a safety agency dedicated to saving lives, FHWA has identified improving roadway safety and mobility as a Vital Few -- one FHWA's top three priorities. The other two Vital Few priorities are Congestion and Environmental Streamlining.
The FHWA Safety Programs focuses on high risk areas, such as road departure, intersections and pedestrian safety, in order to make the biggest difference in improving traffic safety.
To reduce road departure, intersection and pedestrian fatalities by 10% by 2007,
FHWA is focusing on six national target areas, two of which are concerned with road departure. They are as follows:
- Road Departure Fatalities: Reduce run-off-the-road, head-on and opposite direction side-swipe crashes by 10% by 2007. Save 2,514 lives.
- Preventing road departure fatalities from occurring
- Minimizing the severity of road departure crashes
- Intersection Fatalities: Reduce by 10% by 2007. Save 921 lives.
- Pedestrian Fatalities: Reduce by 10% by 2007. Save 475 lives.
- Safety Belt Use: Raise seat belt use to 90% by 2008. Save 5,536 lives.
- Safety Awareness: FHWA is working to make sure that safety is an integral part of planning, project development and operations at the state, MPO and local levels.
- What is the FHWA Doing to Solve This National Safety Problem?
FHWA provides national safety leadership through: conducting innovative safety research; setting national highway safety guidelines; and promoting proven or promising safety technologies.
FHWA is actively pursuing improved roadway safety through a multi-faceted approach in the fields of engineering, education, enforcement, and coordination with public safety agencies (police and fire services).
FHWA also partners with a variety of organizations that are interested in improving roadway safety including: the International Association of Chiefs of Police (IACP), the Institute of Transportation Engineers (ITE), the American Association of State Highway and Transportation Officials (AASHTO), State Departments of Transportation, the National Association of County Engineers (NACE), the American Public Works Association (APWA) the Governors Highway Safety Association (GHSA), the Transportation Research Board (TRB), the American Automobile Association (AAA), the Association of Metropolitan Planning Organizations (AMPO), and National Association of Regional Councils (NARC).
Engineering
On the engineering front, FHWA both conducts research and supports private sector research into a variety of innovative design features that create safer roads, intersections and pedestrian crossings.
Road safety design features that help to reduce road departures and minimize the severity of roadway crashes include: rumble strips, retroreflective signs, and forgiving roadside hardware (i.e. guardrails and breakaway poles), skid resistance pavements, and all-weather pavement markings.
Intersection safety design features that make intersections safer for drivers and pedestrians include: traffic signal timing, improved signage, exclusive turn lanes, and roundabouts.
Pedestrian safety design features that create safer pedestrian crossings for all pedestrians, including those with disabilities include: pedestrian-signal timings and pedestrian signals; improved lighting to enhance visibility; truncated domes for blind pedestrians; and refuge islands on a median.
In addition, FHWA is currently developing the Interactive Highway Safety Design Model (IHSDM) software -- an innovative road safety evaluation software that marshals available safety knowledge into a useful form for highway planners and designers.
FHWA is also actively promoting the use of proven or promising safety technologies that will help improve roadway safety including: rumble strips, retroreflective signs and pavement markings, and roundabouts. As the federal agency responsible for setting national highway safety guidelines, FHWA issued a technical advisory on rumble strips; is working on national guidelines for minimum sign retroreflectivity levels; and published a comprehensive information guide on roundabouts.
Education
FHWA's safety program has a strong educational component. Through a variety of educational tools and workshops, FHWA is dedicated to improving public safety awareness and updating highway engineers and roadway planners on the latest safety research.
To this end, FHWA has funded and sponsored numerous videos, handbooks, websites, multilingual brochures, CDs, manuals, computer modeling software, clearinghouses and training courses. Although these educational materials and courses are too many to detail here, a few are listed below.
For example, FHWA funded and sponsored the Pedestrian Safety Roadshow (PSRS), a four-hour educational workshop that is designed for use by community leaders, concerned citizens, and business leaders. The purpose of PSRS is twofold: to assist communities in developing their own approach to pedestrian safety and to increase awareness of pedestrian safety concerns.
Also, to help roadway planners and engineers apply the latest research and technologies on the needs of older drivers and pedestrians, FHWA published The Older Driver Highway Design Handbook and also offer a one-day workshop.
Enforcement
As part of our comprehensive safety program, FHWA engineers work closely with state highway engineers and law enforcement officials to identify appropriate engineering safety countermeasures for high risk locations and for new roads. Working with state and local law enforcement is one of the ways that FHWA makes sure that roadway safety is always a top priority.
Partnership Activities
FHWA believes that partnerships create synergy and are very important to improving roadway safety. FHWA participates in roadway safety partnerships with state and local officials, concerned citizens, local business leaders, schools and youth organizations. The partnership activities listed below are just a few of the safety partnerships that FHWA participates in. More information on FHWA partnership activities can be found on the FHWA Office of Safety web site.
FHWA's top partnership is working with AASHTO on the AASHTO Strategic Highway Safety Plan (SHSP). The goal is to reduce the annual number of highway deaths by 9,000 by 2008 to a rate of 1.0 (down from the current rate of 1.5). This will accomplished through improved safety in 22 key areas concerning infrastructure, vehicles, drivers, and emergency medical services (EMS). FHWA's role is that of providing national leadership, direction, and the development and demonstration of new safety innovations, technologies, and programs. (For more information.)
The successful National Work-Zone Safety Information Clearinghouse website is a good example of what can be accomplished when FHWA partners with other roadway safety groups. It was created in a partnership by FHWA and the American Road and Transportation Builders Association (ARTBA) and the Texas Transportation Institute (TTI) handles the site's day-to-day operations. The National Utility Contractors Associations (NUCA) and the Institute of Transportation Engineers (ITE) assist ARTBA in marketing and publicizing the clearinghouse.
Started in 1995 by FHWA, Stop Red Light Running (SRLR) is a national initiative to improve intersection safety by reducing the number of red light running incidents. The American Trauma Society became a partner with FHWA in 1998. Over 200 communities, including local law enforcement departments, are currently part of t his nationwide safety program.
In addition, FHWA is a founding member of the Safety Conscious Planning (SCP) Working Group. This group is a national organization dedicated to providing state and metropolitan planners with “best
practices' and opportunities to integrate safety in the planning process. Other partners in the SCP Working Group include: AASHTO, TRB, GHSA, AAA, AMPO, NARC, ITE, and FHWA's DOT sister agencies -- NHTSA, FTA, and FMCSA. For more information on SCP publications and projects there are two web site addresses.
The extensive implementation of yellow-green fluorescent signs around heavily traveled pedestrian crosswalks at school zones, hospitals and airports, is a visible, day-to-day result of successful FHWA and local community partnerships. To improve pedestrian safety through the use of this new pedestrian sign, FHWA partnered with local police departments, schools and hospitals. This new sign has proven to be more visible than the standard, non-fluorescent yellow sign that had been previously used to warn motorists of pedestrian crossings.
Who Is Responsible for Roadway Safety?
Everyone. We all are responsible for driving, walking, and biking safely on our Nation's roads. The engineers and planners have the responsibility to make sure that roads are designed and operating properly -- with safety for all road users in mind. Drivers and pedestrians have the responsibility to always be alert and obey the traffic rules. Passengers should always buckle up and act responsibly. The police and the courts have the responsibility to make sure that the traffic and pedestrian laws are enforced. Public safety agencies have the responsibility of responding to and securing crash locations and enforcing traffic laws. Local communities and county and state governments need to allocate funding for safe roads and increase public awareness about road safety. Everyone should take responsibility for roadway safety.
10 Tips for Driving and Walking Safely
1. It's your responsibility to drive and walk safely so always be alert and attentive to the motorists and pedestrians around you.
2. Never drink and drive. And don't let friends drive drunk.
3. Always buckle up. The life you save could be your own.
4. Obey traffic signals and signs. They are there to keep you and others safe.
5. Make sure you have plenty of time to get to your destination so you don't feel pressured to speed or disobey traffic signals.
6. Don't give into road rage. Your life and the lives of your passengers are more important than angrily reacting to an irresponsible driver.
7. Pedestrians should always wear light-colored or reflective clothing at night to be more visible to drivers.
8. Before you take a left turn at an intersection, make sure it is safe to do so. (More than one-third of all deaths to vehicle occupants occur in side-impact crashes. Most of these occur at intersections.)
9. Obey the speed limits and make sure you drive carefully through intersections and work zones.
10. Don't drive when you are drowsy. If you are drowsy, pull over at a rest area and take a nap before proceeding.
Labels:
AAA,
AASHTO,
AMPO,
and FMCSA,
bicycle safety,
DOT,
FHWA,
FTA,
GHSA,
intersection safety,
ITE,
NARC,
NHTSA,
pedestrian safety,
roadway safety,
TRB
Sunday, November 25, 2007
August 14, 2005 (Houston I-45) Worried residents voice opposition to freeway expansion plan
Worried residents voice opposition to freeway expansion plan
Gene Apodaca
ABC13 Eyewitness News(8/14/05 - HOUSTON) - Hundreds of residents faced off with the Texas Department of Transportation. They're worried about a proposed plan to expand Interstate 45 and they made their concerns heard at a town hall meeting.
Residents are concerned that under the proposed plan their homes would be in jeopardy. Now they're asking the state to look at other alternatives.
For more than 30 years Maria Hurtado has worked to make her Woodland Heights house a home. But now she worries an expansion project could leave her homeless. She said, "I'm still paying on my house. I'm very close to finishing the payments." Hurtado was one of about 800 concerned residents packing Davis High School Saturday. Each was worried about what the proposed I-45 expansion would mean for them.
Heights resident Robin Franklin said, "Destruction of quality of life, taking out homes." "If they take more land than they need and more than the public is willing to give, then it's a lose-lose situation," explained Terry O'Conner, a Woodland Heights resident.
Last month, the Texas Department of Transportation presented its preferred plan for expansion. It's a plan calling for the addition of four managed lanes along I-45 in addition to the existing eight lanes already there. But critics say there are better plans out there. Some want a tunnel to be built, sparing neighboring communities..
Ken Lindow with the I-45 Coalition explained, "We're concerned about losing our homes. We're concerned about more noise, more pollution."
On Saturday, TX-DOT promised to take the suggestions into consideration. "I hope this is a wakeup call to all our mobility advocates and leaders, that you have to listen to the public," said US Rep Sheila Jackson Lee.
A final plan isn't expected until at least October. Until then, those like Hurtado can only wait and worry about their homes. It's estimated that some 90,000 residents would be affected under the current plan.
(Copyright © 2005, KTRK-TV)
Gene Apodaca
ABC13 Eyewitness News(8/14/05 - HOUSTON) - Hundreds of residents faced off with the Texas Department of Transportation. They're worried about a proposed plan to expand Interstate 45 and they made their concerns heard at a town hall meeting.
Residents are concerned that under the proposed plan their homes would be in jeopardy. Now they're asking the state to look at other alternatives.
For more than 30 years Maria Hurtado has worked to make her Woodland Heights house a home. But now she worries an expansion project could leave her homeless. She said, "I'm still paying on my house. I'm very close to finishing the payments." Hurtado was one of about 800 concerned residents packing Davis High School Saturday. Each was worried about what the proposed I-45 expansion would mean for them.
Heights resident Robin Franklin said, "Destruction of quality of life, taking out homes." "If they take more land than they need and more than the public is willing to give, then it's a lose-lose situation," explained Terry O'Conner, a Woodland Heights resident.
Last month, the Texas Department of Transportation presented its preferred plan for expansion. It's a plan calling for the addition of four managed lanes along I-45 in addition to the existing eight lanes already there. But critics say there are better plans out there. Some want a tunnel to be built, sparing neighboring communities..
Ken Lindow with the I-45 Coalition explained, "We're concerned about losing our homes. We're concerned about more noise, more pollution."
On Saturday, TX-DOT promised to take the suggestions into consideration. "I hope this is a wakeup call to all our mobility advocates and leaders, that you have to listen to the public," said US Rep Sheila Jackson Lee.
A final plan isn't expected until at least October. Until then, those like Hurtado can only wait and worry about their homes. It's estimated that some 90,000 residents would be affected under the current plan.
(Copyright © 2005, KTRK-TV)
Friday, November 23, 2007
Cracking China's car market
Cracking China's car market
By Steve Schifferes
Globalisation reporter, BBC News, Liuzhou, Guangxi Province, China
The sleepy, provincial town of Liuzhou is more than 1,200 miles (1,931km) from Shanghai, and 10,000 miles from Detroit. Yet for General Motors, which Toyota claims to have overtaken as the world's largest car company, it is Liuzhou rather than Detroit where the company's future may be decided.
GM has come to Liuzhou to produce a tiny minivan, the Wuling Sunshine, which is a best-seller in China, selling more than 460,000 vehicles a year. The van costs $3,700 (£1,872), has a 0.8 litre engine, have a top speed of 60 mph, and weighs less than 1000kg - yet cheap labour costs mean that GM makes a substantial profit on each vehicle it sells.
Rather than use automation, the Wuling Sunshine is made on an old-fashioned assembly line, which would not look out of date in 1940s Detroit. But with labour costs of just $4 per hour - half the rate in Shanghai - GM Asia Pacific boss Nick Reilly says that the company is only spending $100 per vehicle on labour - and the factory is working around the clock on a three-shift system.
Now GM is investing $350m in building a modern engine plant on the site of the Wuling factory to build 1.1 litre engines, which will open in August, and has expanded production by acquiring another factory in Qingdao. It is the opposite of GM's North American strategy, which has concentrated on selling big, expensive SUVs and trucks - a strategy now threatened by higher petrol prices and changing consumer tastes.
For GM boss Rick Wagoner, China represents a "new model" of production, where the company can make money again as a volume producer of cheap cars, unhindered by union contracts and huge fixed costs.
Rush to China
GM is not alone in identifying China as its key market for the future. There will soon be more cars in China than the US. China's car market grew 25% last year and it has overtaken Japan to be the second-largest car market in the world with sales of 8 million vehicles, including light trucks and minivans.
But with just six car owners per 100 people, compared with 90% car ownership in the US and 80% in the UK, the potential for growth is enormous. According to the research company AC Nielsen, China also has more people who aspire to own a car, but currently do not, than any other country. Also, analysts Roland Berger Associates estimate that the worldwide demand for small cars will rise by 30% in the next decade.
But with the average income in China less than $3,000 a year, reaching the mass market in China is a very different exercise to selling cars in the US or Europe.
Rural marketing
According to James Hu, the sales director of GM-Wuling, the typical Sunshine minivan buyer is male, a small businessman, a high school graduate, and earns between $200 and $500 per month. Over 80% are first-time buyers and most plan to use their minivans for both home and business - sometimes replacing the three-wheeled bicycles in which they used to transport their goods.
Most pay in cash, with sometimes the whole family coming into the dealership with the money in hand. Wuling markets the vehicle through rural China and is expanding its dealer network, which is strong in the poorer, Western regions. In some smaller cities, it shows films in town squares to attract customers.
Fierce competition
Wuling also markets GM's low-priced entry-level car, the Chevrolet Spark, which was designed in Korea. But the Spark, which sells 40,000 vehicles a year, is facing fierce competition from Chinese rivals, especially the Chery-made QQ, which GM at one time accused of stealing its design.
The Chery QQ is 10,000 yuan (£658) cheaper than the Spark and according to vice president Jin Yibo it can compete successfully with the Spark because it has lower development costs. Its sells four times as many small cars as GM. Chery - also based away from coastal China, in Anhui province - is aggressively rolling out new models, including a new A1 compact that was one of the stars at the Shanghai Motor Show.
Overall, rising competition is causing the price of new cars in China to fall by between 7% and 8% per year - cutting into the profit margins of companies like GM.
Rich toys
But China is still a diverse market. Buick is marketed as a luxury brand in China. While GM is selling minivans in rural areas, it is also building and marketing Buicks and Cadillacs in Shanghai, where the Buick van has become a status symbol for companies.
Although the number of private car owners is increasing rapidly, an important part of the Chinese car market is still corporate, especially in the rich coastal cities. With chauffeur-driven cars customary for executives, GM found that the most important modification it had to make for the Chinese market was to increase the size and comfort of the back seat, where the company bosses tend to sit.
GM has even designed a new concept-car version of the Buick at its China-PATAC design centre. But the luxury market is also getting crowded, as multinationals such as Toyota launch their own luxury brands in China. And GM's joint venture approach - its Buicks are built with state-owned Shanghai Automotive Industy Corporation - means it has given its potential rivals access to its technology.
Opportunity
It is not just car companies that are flooding into China. Consumer companies and retailers from around the world are rushing to capitalise on the world's third-largest economy, which has been growing at a rate of 10% per year for two decades.
For most multinationals, Chinese consumers, not Chinese workers, are now their main focus. But understanding how to make a profit in this crowded and diverse market is the real challenge. This is part of series on how globalisation is changing China. Future articles will look at the financial services industry, China's drive overseas, and how Shanghai is tackling pollution.
By Steve Schifferes
Globalisation reporter, BBC News, Liuzhou, Guangxi Province, China
The sleepy, provincial town of Liuzhou is more than 1,200 miles (1,931km) from Shanghai, and 10,000 miles from Detroit. Yet for General Motors, which Toyota claims to have overtaken as the world's largest car company, it is Liuzhou rather than Detroit where the company's future may be decided.
GM has come to Liuzhou to produce a tiny minivan, the Wuling Sunshine, which is a best-seller in China, selling more than 460,000 vehicles a year. The van costs $3,700 (£1,872), has a 0.8 litre engine, have a top speed of 60 mph, and weighs less than 1000kg - yet cheap labour costs mean that GM makes a substantial profit on each vehicle it sells.
Rather than use automation, the Wuling Sunshine is made on an old-fashioned assembly line, which would not look out of date in 1940s Detroit. But with labour costs of just $4 per hour - half the rate in Shanghai - GM Asia Pacific boss Nick Reilly says that the company is only spending $100 per vehicle on labour - and the factory is working around the clock on a three-shift system.
Now GM is investing $350m in building a modern engine plant on the site of the Wuling factory to build 1.1 litre engines, which will open in August, and has expanded production by acquiring another factory in Qingdao. It is the opposite of GM's North American strategy, which has concentrated on selling big, expensive SUVs and trucks - a strategy now threatened by higher petrol prices and changing consumer tastes.
For GM boss Rick Wagoner, China represents a "new model" of production, where the company can make money again as a volume producer of cheap cars, unhindered by union contracts and huge fixed costs.
Rush to China
GM is not alone in identifying China as its key market for the future. There will soon be more cars in China than the US. China's car market grew 25% last year and it has overtaken Japan to be the second-largest car market in the world with sales of 8 million vehicles, including light trucks and minivans.
But with just six car owners per 100 people, compared with 90% car ownership in the US and 80% in the UK, the potential for growth is enormous. According to the research company AC Nielsen, China also has more people who aspire to own a car, but currently do not, than any other country. Also, analysts Roland Berger Associates estimate that the worldwide demand for small cars will rise by 30% in the next decade.
But with the average income in China less than $3,000 a year, reaching the mass market in China is a very different exercise to selling cars in the US or Europe.
Rural marketing
According to James Hu, the sales director of GM-Wuling, the typical Sunshine minivan buyer is male, a small businessman, a high school graduate, and earns between $200 and $500 per month. Over 80% are first-time buyers and most plan to use their minivans for both home and business - sometimes replacing the three-wheeled bicycles in which they used to transport their goods.
Most pay in cash, with sometimes the whole family coming into the dealership with the money in hand. Wuling markets the vehicle through rural China and is expanding its dealer network, which is strong in the poorer, Western regions. In some smaller cities, it shows films in town squares to attract customers.
Fierce competition
Wuling also markets GM's low-priced entry-level car, the Chevrolet Spark, which was designed in Korea. But the Spark, which sells 40,000 vehicles a year, is facing fierce competition from Chinese rivals, especially the Chery-made QQ, which GM at one time accused of stealing its design.
The Chery QQ is 10,000 yuan (£658) cheaper than the Spark and according to vice president Jin Yibo it can compete successfully with the Spark because it has lower development costs. Its sells four times as many small cars as GM. Chery - also based away from coastal China, in Anhui province - is aggressively rolling out new models, including a new A1 compact that was one of the stars at the Shanghai Motor Show.
Overall, rising competition is causing the price of new cars in China to fall by between 7% and 8% per year - cutting into the profit margins of companies like GM.
Rich toys
But China is still a diverse market. Buick is marketed as a luxury brand in China. While GM is selling minivans in rural areas, it is also building and marketing Buicks and Cadillacs in Shanghai, where the Buick van has become a status symbol for companies.
Although the number of private car owners is increasing rapidly, an important part of the Chinese car market is still corporate, especially in the rich coastal cities. With chauffeur-driven cars customary for executives, GM found that the most important modification it had to make for the Chinese market was to increase the size and comfort of the back seat, where the company bosses tend to sit.
GM has even designed a new concept-car version of the Buick at its China-PATAC design centre. But the luxury market is also getting crowded, as multinationals such as Toyota launch their own luxury brands in China. And GM's joint venture approach - its Buicks are built with state-owned Shanghai Automotive Industy Corporation - means it has given its potential rivals access to its technology.
Opportunity
It is not just car companies that are flooding into China. Consumer companies and retailers from around the world are rushing to capitalise on the world's third-largest economy, which has been growing at a rate of 10% per year for two decades.
For most multinationals, Chinese consumers, not Chinese workers, are now their main focus. But understanding how to make a profit in this crowded and diverse market is the real challenge. This is part of series on how globalisation is changing China. Future articles will look at the financial services industry, China's drive overseas, and how Shanghai is tackling pollution.
Labels:
China,
GM,
Liuzhou,
marketing,
Rick Wagoner,
Wuling Sunshine
May 27, 2007 Can Shanghai turn green and grow?
Can Shanghai turn green and grow?
By Steve Schifferes
Shanghai has been transformed into a global city - but its rapid growth has produced pollution, traffic jams and overcrowding. In becoming one of the centres of the world economy, Shanghai has grown faster than almost any other global city in the past 15 years. The population increased from 13.5 million to 21.5 million as migrant labourers flooded in from the surrounding countryside, and the standard of living rose even faster, with per capita income now at $7,000, the highest in China.
The physical size of the city increased sixfold, from just 100 sq km to 680 sq km, as people sought more space and the city government rushed to develop nearby areas, such as Pudong. Three ring roads and six motorways now criss-cross the city, and gridlock grips the bridges and tunnels across the Huangpu river during rush hours.
The city has also seen an explosion in car ownership, with over 1 million car owners in 2006, and private car ownership has doubled in two years. The increased traffic levels contributed to rising levels of atmospheric pollution. Now the city of Shanghai has begun to tackle some of the environmental problems that could threaten its future growth.
Building new towns
Despite its size, Shanghai is still much more densely populated than Western cities, with four times more people per square kilometre than New York. And according to Michael Kwok, head of the architectural consultants Arup in Shanghai, there is very little land left to build on in the central city, after a decade of rapid development. So Shanghai's planners want to limit population growth in the centre by building satellite towns in the outskirts.
Like the UK's New Towns, constructed not long after World War Two to disperse population out of London's most overcrowded districts, the idea is to provide cheaper housing and jobs to attract people to leave congested areas.
Under Shanghai's "One City - Nine Towns" plan, Shanghai is planning nine new cities which will eventually house 500,000 people each. Six of the cities are themed to look like European cities, including the UK, Germany, Italy, Spain, the Netherlands and Sweden. Thamestown, which opened in October 2006, has themed pubs and Tudor-looking architecture concealing high-rise blocks. But critics say that so far, most of the housing built in such towns is out of reach of ordinary citizens. And they argue that the cities have so far not created enough jobs to prevent most residents from commuting into Shanghai, adding to transportation pressures.
Discouraging car ownership
Shanghai has made it expensive to own a car in the city. The city sets a strict limit on the number of licences it will issue for private car ownership - currently around 80,000 per year - and then auctions them off. With the high demand for cars, the current cost of getting a car license in Shanghai is over 40,000 RMB ($5,500; £2,750).
However, a significant factor in Shanghai is the use of cars - and minivans - by private businesses. Over half of all cars in Shanghai are owned by companies - who are less sensitive to financial constraints.
Investment in public transport
(The modern metro carries 1.8 million a day) According to Professor Chen of Tongji University School of Transportation Engineering, the city is now investing heavily in public transport. Since the mid-1990s, it has built an extensive metro system, with five lines, now used by 1.8 million people per day, and it is now planning six new lines. If it carries out all its plans, the length of the system will exceed London's, the world's biggest.
Buses and the poor
Overall, one-quarter of journeys in Shanghai are by public transport, and the city would like to increase that to 30% by 2010. According to Professor Chen, that will mean boosting the numbers who ride the buses as well. Shanghai has more than 1,000 bus routes, run by a variety of private bus companies, but the system of interchanges between lines is confusing and expensive. She has convinced the city that it should make all transfers free in order to encourage more people to ride the system.
Bicycles and scooters
Despite the spread of car ownership, two-thirds of private journeys in Shanghai are by two-wheeled vehicles such as bicycles and scooters. The city has already banned larger motorbikes, and has introduced restrictions on bikes on the many commuter highways in the city. But it is also building 180km of dedicated bike lanes, especially in newly built areas like Pudong, where bicycles will be segregated from scooters.
Affluence and growth
Shanghai has had some success in tackling its environmental issues. One fact has been a strong planning system, coupled with the fact that the government owns all the land. This has allowed the rapid redevelopment of the city and its infrastructure - as well as generating money to pay for big infrastructure projects.
Air quality has improved with unacceptable days dropping from 20% to 10% in the past five years. But water pollution, is worse, as the rapid growth of industry in the Shanghai region, upstream of the city, has made it harder to keep the city's main water source, the Yangtze River, clean.
Human cost
The city's speed at developing its infrastructure has also come with a human cost, with millions of people displaced for public and private building projects. According to Michael Kwok, in the early days of Shanghai's development it was relatively easy to relocate people to outlying areas, but now people are demanding more compensation.
More broadly, Shanghai is the still the embodiment of China's economic dream of living in an affluent society on a Western scale. Those aspirations - for more land and housing, as well as more consumer durables like cars and air conditioners - are likely to put further pressure on Shanghai's environment in the future.
This is part of a series on how globalisation is changing China's largest city, Shanghai. Further articles will explore the issue of migrant labour and look at plans for an eco-city.
By Steve Schifferes
Shanghai has been transformed into a global city - but its rapid growth has produced pollution, traffic jams and overcrowding. In becoming one of the centres of the world economy, Shanghai has grown faster than almost any other global city in the past 15 years. The population increased from 13.5 million to 21.5 million as migrant labourers flooded in from the surrounding countryside, and the standard of living rose even faster, with per capita income now at $7,000, the highest in China.
The physical size of the city increased sixfold, from just 100 sq km to 680 sq km, as people sought more space and the city government rushed to develop nearby areas, such as Pudong. Three ring roads and six motorways now criss-cross the city, and gridlock grips the bridges and tunnels across the Huangpu river during rush hours.
The city has also seen an explosion in car ownership, with over 1 million car owners in 2006, and private car ownership has doubled in two years. The increased traffic levels contributed to rising levels of atmospheric pollution. Now the city of Shanghai has begun to tackle some of the environmental problems that could threaten its future growth.
Building new towns
Despite its size, Shanghai is still much more densely populated than Western cities, with four times more people per square kilometre than New York. And according to Michael Kwok, head of the architectural consultants Arup in Shanghai, there is very little land left to build on in the central city, after a decade of rapid development. So Shanghai's planners want to limit population growth in the centre by building satellite towns in the outskirts.
Like the UK's New Towns, constructed not long after World War Two to disperse population out of London's most overcrowded districts, the idea is to provide cheaper housing and jobs to attract people to leave congested areas.
Under Shanghai's "One City - Nine Towns" plan, Shanghai is planning nine new cities which will eventually house 500,000 people each. Six of the cities are themed to look like European cities, including the UK, Germany, Italy, Spain, the Netherlands and Sweden. Thamestown, which opened in October 2006, has themed pubs and Tudor-looking architecture concealing high-rise blocks. But critics say that so far, most of the housing built in such towns is out of reach of ordinary citizens. And they argue that the cities have so far not created enough jobs to prevent most residents from commuting into Shanghai, adding to transportation pressures.
Discouraging car ownership
Shanghai has made it expensive to own a car in the city. The city sets a strict limit on the number of licences it will issue for private car ownership - currently around 80,000 per year - and then auctions them off. With the high demand for cars, the current cost of getting a car license in Shanghai is over 40,000 RMB ($5,500; £2,750).
However, a significant factor in Shanghai is the use of cars - and minivans - by private businesses. Over half of all cars in Shanghai are owned by companies - who are less sensitive to financial constraints.
Investment in public transport
(The modern metro carries 1.8 million a day) According to Professor Chen of Tongji University School of Transportation Engineering, the city is now investing heavily in public transport. Since the mid-1990s, it has built an extensive metro system, with five lines, now used by 1.8 million people per day, and it is now planning six new lines. If it carries out all its plans, the length of the system will exceed London's, the world's biggest.
Buses and the poor
Overall, one-quarter of journeys in Shanghai are by public transport, and the city would like to increase that to 30% by 2010. According to Professor Chen, that will mean boosting the numbers who ride the buses as well. Shanghai has more than 1,000 bus routes, run by a variety of private bus companies, but the system of interchanges between lines is confusing and expensive. She has convinced the city that it should make all transfers free in order to encourage more people to ride the system.
Bicycles and scooters
Despite the spread of car ownership, two-thirds of private journeys in Shanghai are by two-wheeled vehicles such as bicycles and scooters. The city has already banned larger motorbikes, and has introduced restrictions on bikes on the many commuter highways in the city. But it is also building 180km of dedicated bike lanes, especially in newly built areas like Pudong, where bicycles will be segregated from scooters.
Affluence and growth
Shanghai has had some success in tackling its environmental issues. One fact has been a strong planning system, coupled with the fact that the government owns all the land. This has allowed the rapid redevelopment of the city and its infrastructure - as well as generating money to pay for big infrastructure projects.
Air quality has improved with unacceptable days dropping from 20% to 10% in the past five years. But water pollution, is worse, as the rapid growth of industry in the Shanghai region, upstream of the city, has made it harder to keep the city's main water source, the Yangtze River, clean.
Human cost
The city's speed at developing its infrastructure has also come with a human cost, with millions of people displaced for public and private building projects. According to Michael Kwok, in the early days of Shanghai's development it was relatively easy to relocate people to outlying areas, but now people are demanding more compensation.
More broadly, Shanghai is the still the embodiment of China's economic dream of living in an affluent society on a Western scale. Those aspirations - for more land and housing, as well as more consumer durables like cars and air conditioners - are likely to put further pressure on Shanghai's environment in the future.
This is part of a series on how globalisation is changing China's largest city, Shanghai. Further articles will explore the issue of migrant labour and look at plans for an eco-city.
Labels:
bicycles,
car ownership,
China,
globalisation,
public transportation,
Shanghai,
urbanisation
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)